• 検索結果がありません。

Caregivers’ Preferences for Alleviating Burden of Long-term Care of Japanese Elderly at Home

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

シェア "Caregivers’ Preferences for Alleviating Burden of Long-term Care of Japanese Elderly at Home"

Copied!
16
0
0

読み込み中.... (全文を見る)

全文

(1)

Caregivers’ Preferences for Alleviating Burden of Long-term Care of Japanese Elderly at Home

Taro Ohdoko Fan Zhang

Abstract

Preferences to alleviate the burden imposed on caregivers by caring for the elderly have not been investigated due to features that cannot be directly observed. We conducted choice experiments (CE) on the attributes of care services provided to the elderly at home throughout Japan to estimate caregivers’ preferences for care plans.The caregivers prefer care plans that consist of more formal care and day-time services, while less time should be spent in care by the family. Care payments should also be made weekly. We also found that caregivers reached a consensus that there was excessive burden imposed when family members were involved in informal long- term care since their heterogeneity of preferences was more moderate than that of caregivers who were not supported by family members.We found that we should take into consideration the implementation of certain compensation schemes to alleviate the burden imposed on family members. We suggest some example compensation schemes from overseas that are suited to the Japanese situation.

Key words: Elderly care burden, choice experiment, informal care, random parameter logit model, compensation scheme

1 Introduction

The Ministry of Health, Labour and Welfare (MHLW) has been conducting and man- aging an insurance system for elderly care and formal-care services since April 1, 2000

This work was supported in part by the 21st Century Center of Excellence Program associated with the Graduate School of Economics and the Research Institute for Economics and Business Administration at Kobe University. In addition, this study was supported by Grants-in-Aid for Scientific Research (20330061) made by the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science. We greatly appreciate the support and advice given by the administrators of the 21st Century Center of Excellence Program, the assistance given by the Nursing Care Insurance Department of the city of Sanda, and the replies given by many respondents who were kind enough to answer the questions we posed to them.

Graduate School of Economics, Kobe University Rokkodai-cho, Nada, Kobe 657-8501, Phone: +81- 90-7878-2442 Email: ohdoko@jazz.email.ne.jp

Research and Investigation Center, Hyogo Earthquake Memorial 21st Century Research Institute

!"#$%&%

'()

(2)

throughout Japan. The system has ensured that beneficiaries pay fees more transpar- ently. Since there are increasing quantities and sorts of formal-care services, the elderly in Japan have become familiar with using the system. As the burden of elderly care has been increasing, formal care should become more professional and better organized.

The number of caregivers should be increased not only from the viewpoint of welfare economics but also from that of labor economics. Formal care can become one of the largest industries in Japan.

However, the present system has recently been confronted by crises that threaten its eradication. There have been prevailing overuses of formal care coupled with economic deflation, which have led to the financial crisis. If these cannot be rectified, evidence has shown that the social costs of long-term care will increasingly induce breakdowns in society (Grabowski and Gruber (2007)) throughout Japan. There have been some cases of overuse where care receivers who require comparatively low degrees of care in Japan have been over-serviced. It is high time that the system and the overall concept were improved. We in Japan should take into consideration not just formal care but informal care to cope with deficiencies in the system and avoid the adverse effects the financial crisis is having on long-term-care services.

We need to investigate what people prefer and how they perceive the burden of elderly care to consider informal care. Since informal care tends to be given by family members of the elderly, it is often overlooked, which has led to the scarcity of existing studies, especially from the microeconomic perspective in Japan. The preference structure or demand by family members for informal care should be clarified. We need to conduct in- person surveys and construct a national database for informal care, neither of which has been implemented in Japan. According to Fujisawa and Colombo (2009), the number of long-term care recipients and elderly people are increasing not only in Japan but all over East Asia, such as in South Korea. Furthermore, they state that “it is not unusual for intensive informal carers to incur health or mental problems themselves” (Fujisawa and Colombo (2009), p.5). It seems possible to extend to housekeepers or part-time workers the notion that informal care still plays an important role in how well-developed formal care will be. Thus, political considerations on how we have to treat informal/formal

(3)

care should be conducted with the use of scientific evidence such as that from in-person surveys around the region of East Asia.

Informal care has been increasingly treated as an urgent topic in health economics.

Van Houtven and Norton (2004) investigated the possibility of substituting informal care given by adult children with formal care by using 1998 Health and Retirement Surveys (HRS) and 1995 Asset and Health Dynamics in the Oldest-Old Panel Survey (AHEAD) in the United States. In their study, formal-care services were used as dependent vari- ables and the hours of informal care with numerous demographic statistics were used as independent variables. Although HRS and AHEAD represent excellent panel data on in-person surveys, there are no comparable databases to match these in Japan1 . It has been concluded that informal care reduces home health-care use and delays entry into nursing homes.

AHEAD was also used by Charles and Sevak (2005). They investigated the relation- ship between informal care and nursing-home entry. This study focused on the effect of substituting informal caregivers with institutional care since nursing is often given in certain institutions. They indicated that there was a negative correlation, which led to a reduced risk of nursing-home entry caused by informal care.

Bolin et al. (2007) researched the relationship between informal and formal care by using Surveys of Health, Ageing and Retirement in Europe (SHARE). They found from their results on almost all countries in the European Union 1) that informal and formal care can be substituted, 2) that informal care complements doctor or hospital care, and 3) that there are more informal caregivers in southern Europe than in the north, which is compatible with the cultural context. In addition, SHARE also provides an excellent survey database just like AHEAD.

The conventional perspective is that daughters tend to be better caregivers than sons. Van Houten and Norton (2008) analyzed the effect of substituting informal medical caregivers and associated the results with their gender and marital status in the United States. As a result of using Standard Analytic Files of Medicare Claims (SAFMC) and

1MHLW has been conducted Comprehensive Survey of Living Conditions, which data is available in the website (http://www.mhlw.go.jp/english/database/db-hss/cslc-index.html). They collect personal responses as for long term care, such as “caring time by main care-taker living with persons requiring care by level of long-term care”. However, there are no thorough panel survey data like AHEAD in Japan.

(4)

AHEAD, they found that gender did not matter, married children were less effective caregivers than those who remained unmarried, and the related costs of medical care for single elderly could be reduced by their children.

Van den Berg and Ferrer-i-Carbonell (2007) evaluated the monetary value of providing informal care. They used a Likert scale for a “happiness question” as dependent variables from mail survey data in the Netherlands. They found that an extra hour of informal care is worth about eight or nine Euros if the care recipient is a family member, while this is seven or nine Euros if he/she is not2. They concluded their methods could include all costs and effects associated with informal caregivers, which has scarcely been done before.

It has been demonstrated that informal care can be substituted for formal care, and that the value of informal care should/can be evaluated. To the best of our knowledge, in-person databases and the evaluation of informal care appear to be limited in Japan.

We need to clarify how the burden of elderly care should be treated and evaluated as soon as possible. Thus, we conducted choice experiments (CE) with attributes on elderly-care services provided at home in Japan to estimate the preferences family members had for care plans by explicitly presenting them with the burdens of elderly care . To take their preference heterogeneity into consideration, we used a Random Parameter Logit (RPL) Model with repeated data.

The following sections are organized as follows. We explain the survey design and RPL in Section 2. The estimation results are presented in Section 3. We detail and interpret these results in Section 4 and conclude in Section 5.

2 Materials and Methods

2.1 Survey Design

The mailed survey was conducted in January 2006 in the city of Sanda in Japan. Sanda is located in the south of Hyogo prefecture and is one of the dormitory suburbs of western Japan. Residents of the city provide intensive long-term care for the elderly, which is why we selected it as the area for the survey. This survey was conducted to clarify the

2They simultaneously conducted the Contingent Valuation Method (CVM), which estimated 10.52 Euros per hour to be the cost of informal care.

(5)

current situation with care receivers in the city and the preferences informal caregivers had for care plans for the elderly. The caregivers who were respondents consisted of family members caring for those who were authorized to receive support/care. They were using home or institutional care services. We obtained 1,270 responses from home- care providers from 1,894 mailed surveys (67.1%), and 299 responses from institutional care providers from 509 mailed surveys (58.7%). We decided to use only home-care data since it was much clearer who provided informal/formal care simultaneously than who provided institutional care.

We asked the family caregivers the individual characteristics and CE questions below in our survey. The descriptive statistics are listed in Table 1:

2.2 Choice Experiment

Conjoint analysis is advantageous for simultaneously evaluating several kinds of values or features. Conjoint analysis started with the concept of “Conjoint Measurement” (Luce and Tukey, (1964))3. Then, practical methods were developed for psychometrics and marketing (Louviere et al. (2000)). They asked subjects to choose the best type (Choice Experiment: CE) and rank the types (Contingent Ranking) such that they clarified their preferences for each attribute as options. CE is especially reliable because of its improvements in methodology.

We selected four attributes, i.e., 1) the number of visits by authorized caregivers, 2) the number of day-service uses, which involved formal care, 3) the burden of family care, which involved the burden of informal care by the elderly, and 4) the fees for plans, which involved self-payments by the care receivers with insurance payments excluded4.

The main effect of fractional factorial design was used to decrease the number of profiles out of the full combination of 4×2×4×5 = 160. Twenty profiles were created and the choice sets were created by selecting two profiles randomly with the “no choice”

option attached5. We asked each respondent the CE questions five times.

3Debreu (1960) classified conjoint measurement with cardinal utility theory. However, Luce and Tukey (1964) expressed conjoint measurement with mathematical algebra, which promoted a practical methodology.

4The MHLW in Japan has passed regulations that those being cared for should pay 10% of all costs along with the care plan.

5This is also called the “opt-out” option. Ryan and Sk˚atun (2004) recommended including the “opt-

(6)

Table 1: Descriptive Statistics of Family Caregiver at Home

Items Sub-items No. of Ans. %

Sex of Caregiver Male 139 17.7

Female 189 62.2

No Answer 158 20.1

Age of Caregiver 20+ 3 0.4

30+ 17 2.2

40+ 104 13.2

50+ 234 29.8

60+ 133 16.9

70+ 112 14.2

80+ 26 3.3

90+ 0 0

No Answer 157 20

Mean 59.1

Standard Deviation 11.452

Occupation of Caregiver Self-Employed 61 7.8

Full-Time Job 66 8.4

Part-Time Job 105 13.4

Unemployed 376 47.8

Others 21 2.7

No Answer 157 20

Use of Formal Care at Home Use 206 26.2

Non-Use 351 44.7

No Answer 229 29.1

Mean No. of Uses per Month 11.8

Standard Deviation 11.989

Day Service Use 251 31.9

Non-Use 304 38.7

No Answer 231 29.4

Mean No. of Uses per Month 7.7

Standard Deviation 4.358

2.3 Random Parameter Logit Model

The econometric model is based on the Random Utility Model (RUM, Louviere et al.

(2000)). RUM is used to define the utility of a respondent who chooses alternative iin Eq. (1):

out” option since CE must mimic real behavior to alleviate hypothetical bias.

(7)

Uj =Vi+i =

M

m=1

βmxmi +i (1)

Here,Vi denotes the observable component, whilei denotes the unobservable error com- ponent. Xim(m = 1,· · · , M) denotes M kinds of attributes that consist of the alterna- tives, which come with the marginal utility,βm. The additive separated form is frequently adopted6.

McFadden (1974) proves that the choice probability of i in J alternatives becomes the Conditional Logit (CL) model with the first extreme value distribution assumed on the error component as:

Pj = exp (Vj)

J

j=1exp (Vj) (2)

Revelt and Train (1998) demonstrated that RPL with repeated data to estimate the choice probability with preference heterogeneity could relax the assumptions of CL; they derived preference homogeneity and Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives (IIA). The choice probability of respondent nconsists of7

Pni=

ΠTt=1 exp (Vj)

J

j=1exp (Vj)f(β|Ω) (3) Here,T denotes the number of times that the respondent answered CE and Ω denotes the parameter space of β , such as the mean and standard deviation. We use this definition for the choice probability. Which attribute is preferred heterogeneously can be analyzed by using estimated Ω. The statistic in Eq. (4) below can be estimated by Monte Carlo simulation (Mitani (2009)):

Λ = σ

µ (4)

Here, σ denotes the standard deviation parameters of coefficients, while µ denotes the mean parameters. We did 10,000 simulations to stabilize our analyses.

The implicit price (IP) or marginal willingness to pay of each attribute can be esti- mated as:

6The “true” marginal utility is confounded by the scale parameter, which is proportionate to variance in the error component. The scale parameter is frequently assumed to be unity, which we have also assumed.

7When assuming IIA, the attributes, the characteristics of the alternatives, and/or the error component in the alternatives have been considered to be independent, which is a restriction that is very difficult to overcome.

(8)

IP =−βx

βp (5)

Here,βp denotes the mean parameter of the marginal utility of the price attribute, while βx denotes that of the other attributes.

3 Results

In estimating IP with RPL, we assumed a normal distribution to be a “mixing dis- tribution” which is the probabilistic distribution of coefficients. We used the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) when selecting the model, while we used McFadden s Rho as the index of model fitness. The results are listed in Table 3.

All the mean parameters are statistically significant and compatible with sound intu- ition. More numbers of visits (visits) or day service uses (day) are preferred, while greater family-care burdens (family) or more fees for plans (fees) are considered unfavorable.

Table 2: Attribute Level

Attribute (Unit) Level 1 Level 2 Level 3 Level 4 Level 5

No. of Visits by Authorized Caregiver 0 1 2 3

(times/week)

No. of Day Service Uses (days/week) 0 1

Family-care Burdens (hours/week) 0 4 8 12

Fees for Plans (yen/week) 0 1,000 2,000 3,000 4,000

Figure 1: Choice Set Example

The constant for the no choice option (const) is positively significant, which means every factor that leads to “no choice” is represented by that constant and respondents are

(9)

even satisfied with the decision of “no choice”. Some respondents chose “no choice” in the first/last question of the CE sequence; the others chose from the middle. Therefore, it is possible to say that respondents chose “no choice” when the confronting CE made it too difficult for them to choose Plan A/B. Since “const” is positive, they were satisfied with choosing “no choice”. This suggested that the “no choice” option was required as expected, and that hypothetical bias was reduced in our results.

We then investigated how the marginal utilities were dispersed. The results are listed in Table 4. The dispersion of the coefficient of “family” is most moderate as the absolute value, which means that there are few heterogeneous preferences with the family-care burden compared to the other attributes. Finally, we obtained the IPs of each attribute by using the mean parameters in Table 5.

Each IP means the willingness by family caregivers to pay by themselves. The esti- mated IP of the number of visits ranges from 312 to 6,144 yen/time, while the actual self-payment is approximately set at 210 to 680 yen corresponding to the care within two hours. That of the number of day-service uses ranges from 108 to 12,870 yen/day, while the actual self-payment is approximately set at 290 to 1,400 yen/day. Thus, it seems that family caregivers prefer a great deal of formal care. This suggests that the actual self-payments for formal care can be increased more than they are at the current level.

However, the mean IP of the family burden is -691 yen/hour where the confidence interval ranges from -272 to -3,883, which implies that additional family-care burdens can be monetarily charged up to that level. Thus, this suggests that the burden can be offset by 691 yen/hour at the mean IP, which has to be paid for family caregivers since they were the respondents in this survey.

4 Discussion

Although there were heterogeneous preferences, their structure was compatible to intu- ition even when the family-care burden was explicitly demonstrated. This suggested that there was a consensus view of the family-care burden. They may have accepted that there can excessive burdens when family members informally care for their elderly, which seems to be standard practice throughout Japan.

(10)

Table3:ResultsofRPL EstimatedCoefficientsEstimatedMarginalEffects VariablesCoefficientsTvaluesVariablesinCarePlanA:AVariablesinCarePlanB:BVariablesinNoChoice:N RandomparametersMeanForAForBForNForAForBForNForAForBForN Visits(times/week)0.175***3.3244.276-3.368-0.908-3.4414.726-1.285-0.003-0.0020.005 Day(days/week)0.358*2.3835.535-3.171-2.365-3.1216.993-3.872-0.002-0.0010.003 Family(hours/week)-0.104**-6.47-3.971.5092.461.627-4.6723.0450.0050.003-0.008 Fees(yen/week)-1.505E-04*-2.1735.793-6.8471.054-7.2155.4571.758-0.0010.002-0.001 Fixedparameters Const0.408***3.945n.a.n.a.n.a.n.a.n.a.n.a.n.a.n.a.n.a. StandardDeviation(S.D.)parametersS.D. Visits(times/week)0.613***8.7633.6753.0961.6753.3124.4872.0010.120.1170.223 Day(days/week)1.962***10.765.8683.8253.0363.595.2722.9530.1180.0720.19 Family(hours/week)0.187***11.6063.621.5482.6071.5013.2452.2630.2440.1660.341 Fees(yen/week)9.756E-04***9.7596.3756.172.0886.0766.52.5020.1470.1360.054 HaltonReplication100 Samples809 No.ofObservations3703 LogLikelihood-2953.68 McFadden’sRho Noconstant0.272 Constantonly0.255 Note:***;0.1%,**;1%,*;5%,E0X;10X,n.a.=notapplicable

(11)

Table 4: Dispersion of Coefficients

Visits Day Family Fees

Mean of Λ 3.51 5.381 -1.793 -6.315

(95% Confidence Interval) (2.070 / 8.494) (2.751 / 23.685) (-2.654 / -1.303) (-30.715 / -2.981)

Table 5: Estimated IP

Visits Day Family

Mean of IP 1,163 yen/time 2,379 yen/day -691 yen/hour (95% Confidence Interval) (312 / 6,144) (108 / 12,870) (-272 / -3,883)

Since informal care tends to be free of charge, it has not been compensated especially in Japan. There are five main compensation schemes according to Ungerson (1997).

These are 1) caregiver allowances that are subsidized by taxes and social security systems, 2) proper wages that are paid by the government for informal care, 3) routed wages that are paid by the government via those receiving care, 4) symbolic payments that are paid to the family who are providing care, and 5) paid volunteers who are remunerated by volunteer organizations. Discussion on the implementation of these schemes has been avoided in Japan.

Although the public insurance system for elderly care has compensated caregivers, the system does not work sufficiently well due to numerous problems such as budget deficits. In addition, Japanese informal caregivers seem to be unable to keep on caring for the elderly in the current situation. Because of this, we need to ensure that caregivers will be given allowances or proper wages, or volunteers will be paid by conventional local communities throughout Japan. In addition, exemptions from care insurance should be granted as indirect compensation.

Temporary family caregivers are authorized in Japan in rural areas where the in- surance system is not available such as on isolated islands. This arrangement can be classified as a hybrid between caregiver allowances, proper wages, and paid volunteering.

The wages are paid by the government via certain private organizations of caregivers.

However, it may be difficult to expand this simply since this system involves many re-

(12)

quirements and certain prohibitions such as those in MHLW Order No. 31, which contains standards on the staff of businesses such as those that have designated home services, facilities, and administration.

There are numerous informal care systems that provide allowances in the world (Fu- jisawa and Colombo (2009), Goodhead and McDonald (2007)), which would be helpful to give compensation to caregivers who provide informal care to the elderly throughout Japan. First, there are many countries that administer benefits to employees who have to take care of their family members. One of these is 1) Australia where family caregivers are employees who are paid for less than 20 hours/week; their allowances are not taxable if the caregivers or care recipients are below the legal limit for the age pension. Another is 2) Canada where compassionate care benefits are only given to employees even though there are some legal requirements. Another is 3) Germany where a long-term-care in- surance fund makes contributions to employees who ought to be family caregivers up to a ceiling in the statutory pension scheme. Another country is 4) the United Kingdom where caregivers on low incomes can be fully covered for the basic pension and they can accumulate pension credits based on a low earning threshold. Another country is 5) Sweden where those taking care leave are entitled to pension credits depending on their income. 6) New Zealand gives general benefits rather than those only concentrated on family caregivers. These are authorized by administrative agencies with some legal strategies, such as the United Kingdom Caregivers Strategy introduced in 1999.

Not just direct compensation but indirect compensation should be considered in Japan. Direct compensation advocates that the benefits for employees be reconsidered or improved with reference to systems in other countries (1)-6)). Moreover, general ben- efits and allowances are recommended to support not only employees but other members such as household workers. Indirect compensation involves awarding care-insurance ex- emptions to those who are on child-care leave from their offices. However, there have been no cases of certified exemptions given to those who are on elderly-care leave. To ensure the continuity of care giving by family members, we advocate that the system of care-insurance exemptions be improved as quickly as possible.

According to the IP estimate of the family-care burden, 691 yen/hour should be paid

(13)

to family caregivers on average when awarding certain compensation. In comparison, the minimum wage was set at 712 yen/hour in Hyogo Prefecture including the city of Sanda in 2009. We advocate that a payment level for alleviating the family burden be set, at least, according to the minimum wage8. The financial crisis can be mitigated in part by awarding compensation to alleviate the family burden. The public insurance system has also been paying additional amounts for authorized caregivers visits of, at least, 1,520 yen/hour9. Thus, this suggests that we can decrease the current budget for public-care insurance even when the family burden is compensated for along with the minimum wage with ceteris paribus, even though an additional monitoring system may have to be organized.

5 Concluding Remarks

The preference of caregivers to mitigate the burden of caring for the elderly has not been sufficiently investigated for a long time, especially from a microeconomic perspective.

We conducted a CE by investigating the burden imposed by informal elderly care with attributes of services available at home in Japan to estimate the preferences of caregivers for care plans.

When the burden of care was explicitly treated in CE, caregivers reached a consensus that there was excessive burden when family members were involved in informal care.

Therefore, we clarified that we should take into consideration the construction of some kind of compensation scheme to alleviate the burden on caregivers, especially that on family member. In addition, the discussion on compensation schemes suggested that the minimum wage should be taken into consideration .

We need to further investigate what the best compensation scheme is for Japan, and how the current situation with those receiving care and their caregivers is. We advocated that family caregivers be compensated with direct and general allowances and that care-

8There may have been some disagreement on how the minimum wage has to be calculated. It seems possible to assume respondents in our survey react with reference to the level of the minimum wage at the time of the survey. Thus, we omitted the discussion on the minimum wage.

9The initial payment was set at 2,962 yen/hour. If the care time exceeds one and a half hours, the additional payment is 844 yen per half hour, while the care receiver s self-payment is 85 yen (10% of the total payment). Therefore, the public insurance system has been paying about 1,520 (844×2× 0.9)yen/hour.

(14)

insurance exemptions are awarded to them with reference to systems operating in other countries. It is therefore more necessary than ever before to thoroughly consider what the roles of informal and formal care are and what their relationship is with each other. While many existing studies such as those by Van Houtven and Norton (2004) have advocated substitutive structures for informal and formal care, we should do further research on how these can be implemented in Japan, where social surveys should provide us with beneficial insights into these issues. Within the context of our survey, our intention was not that informal care should be expanded or developed, but that it is properly compensated and this suggested research on how to improve formal care . Each sector that supplies caregivers, either informal or formal, can offer choice options or alternatives if they can be proved to be substitutes for each other. More accurate information on demographics should be collected when conducting surveys. This is much more helpful in targeting political considerations, even though we unfortunately could not find any socio-economic characteristics that were statistically significant covariates of the utility function in this article. When using these covariates, we should be able to determine who should be supported with allowances or exemptions and to what extent.

References

Bolin K., Lindgren B. and Lundborg P. (2008) Informal and Formal Care among Single- Living Elderly in Europe, Health Economics, Vol. 17, pp. 393-409.

Charles K. and Sevak P. (2005) Can Family Caregiving Substitute for Nursing Home Care? , Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 24, pp. 1174-1190.

Fujisawa R. and Colombo F. (2009) The Long-Term Care Workforce: Overview and Strategies to Adapt Supply to a Growing Demand, OECD Health Working Paper No.

44.

Goodhead A. and McDonald J. (2007) Informal Caregivers Literature Review: A Re- port Prepared for the National Health Committee, Health Service Research Center, University of Wellington, http://www.nhc.health.govt.nz/moh.nsf/indexcm/nhc-home (retrieved on Feb. 4th, 2010).

(15)

Grabowski D. and Gruber J. (2007) Moral Hazard in Nursing Home Use, Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 26, pp. 560-577.

Krinsky I. and Robb R. (1986) On Approximating the Statistical Properties of Elasticity, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 68, pp. 715-719.

Louviere J., Hensher D. and Swait J. (2000) Stated Choice Methods: Analysis and Ap- plication, Cambridge Univ. Press, UK.

Luce R. and Tukey J. (1964) Simultaneous Conjoint Measurement: A New Type of Fundamental Measurement, Journal of Mathematical Psychology, Vol.1, pp.1-27.

McFadden D. (1974) Conditional Logit Analysis of Qualitative Choice Behaviour, Fron- tiers in Econometrics, ed. Zarembka P., pp. 105-142, Academic Press, NY.

Mitani, Y. (2009) The Effects of Ecological Information Provision on Preferences for Ecosystem Restoration, prepared paper for Society for Environmental Economics and Policy Studies at Chiba University, September 27th, 2009.

Revelt D. and Train K. (1998) Mixed Logit with Repeated Choice: Households’ Choices of Appliance Efficiency Level, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 80, No. 4, pp.

647-657.

Ryan M. and Skatun D. (2004) Modeling Non-Demanders in Choice Experiments, Health Economics, Vol. 13, pp. 397-402.

Train K. (2009) Discrete Choice Methods with Simulation 2nd eds. Cambridge Univ.

Press, UK.

Ungerson C. (1997) Social Politics and the Commodification of Care,Social Politics, Vol.

4, No. 3, pp. 362-381.

Van den Berg B. and Ferrer-i-Carbonell A. (2007) Monetary Valuation of Informal Care:

The Well-Being Valuation Method, Health Economics, Vol. 16, pp. 1227-1244.

Van Houtven C. and Norton E. (2008) Informal Care and Medicare Expenditures: Testing for Heterogeneous Treatment Effects, Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 27, pp. 134- 156.

(16)

Van Houtven C. and Norton E. (2004) Informal Care and Elderly Health Care Use, Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 23, No. 6, pp. 1159-1180.

Table 1: Descriptive Statistics of Family Caregiver at Home
Table 2: Attribute Level

参照

関連したドキュメント

The only thing left to observe that (−) ∨ is a functor from the ordinary category of cartesian (respectively, cocartesian) fibrations to the ordinary category of cocartesian

If condition (2) holds then no line intersects all the segments AB, BC, DE, EA (if such line exists then it also intersects the segment CD by condition (2) which is impossible due

This means that finding the feasible arrays for distance-regular graphs of valency 4 was reduced to a finite amount of work, but the diameter bounds obtained were not small enough

It is suggested by our method that most of the quadratic algebras for all St¨ ackel equivalence classes of 3D second order quantum superintegrable systems on conformally flat

[56] , Block generalized locally Toeplitz sequences: topological construction, spectral distribution results, and star-algebra structure, in Structured Matrices in Numerical

By the algorithm in [1] for drawing framed link descriptions of branched covers of Seifert surfaces, a half circle should be drawn in each 1–handle, and then these eight half

Our method of proof can also be used to recover the rational homotopy of L K(2) S 0 as well as the chromatic splitting conjecture at primes p > 3 [16]; we only need to use the

For the assessment of the care burden we used the Japanese Version of the Zarit Caregiver Burden Interview (J- ZBI) and compared it with the caregiver’s age, relationship, care term