• 検索結果がありません。

Lec5 最近の更新履歴 yyasuda's website

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2017

シェア "Lec5 最近の更新履歴 yyasuda's website"

Copied!
18
0
0

読み込み中.... (全文を見る)

全文

(1)

ECO290E: Game Theory

(2)

Review of Lecture 4 

  Spatial competition model has a unique NE in which both shops choose the middle point.

Minimal differentiation!

  Political platforms (left/right or liberal/ conservative)

  TV shows (time slots)

  Under the Bertrand model:

  Price will be set at the level of marginal cost even when there are only two competitors.

Huge jump from 1 (monopoly) to 2 (duopoly)!

  Under the Cournot model:

  Total output (price) is between monopoly level and that under perfect competition.

(3)

Zero-Sum Game 

  Matching Pennies:

Player 2 Player 1

Heads Tails

Heads 1 -1

-1 1

Tails -1 1

(4)

No Nash Equilibrium?

 

The distinguishing feature of zero-sum game is that

each player would like to outguess the other since

there is No “win-win” situation.

 

Examples are:

  Porker: bluff or not

  Battle (War): attack/defend by land or by sea

  Tennis: left or right to serve/receive

 

When each player would always like outguess the

other(s), there is no Nash equilibrium.

Is there no solution or stable outcome?

(5)

Mixed Strategy

 

A mixed strategy for a player is a probability

distribution over some (or all) of her strategies.

 

The strategy we have studied so far, i.e., taking some

action for sure, is called a pure-strategy .

 

When the outcome of the game is uncertain, we

assume that each player maximizes expected value of

her payoff.

Expected utility theory (von Neumann and

Morgenstern, 1944)

(6)

Matching Pennies Again 

  Introducing mixed strategies:

Player 2 Player 1

Heads (p) Tails (1-p)

Heads (q)

1 -1

-1 1

Tails (1-q)

-1 1

1 -1

(7)

How to Find Equilibrium?

  If a player takes both “Heads” and “Tails” with positive probability, she must be indifferent between these two pure strategies, i.e., the expected payoff derived by

choosing Heads must be equal to that by choosing Tails.

  Otherwise, it is strictly better for her to choose either H or T for sure; no incentive to mix the strategies.

  -p + (1-p) = p - (1-p), hence p = 0.5.

  q - (1-q) = -q + (1-q), hence q = 0.5.

(8)

How to Verify Equilibrium?

 

Note that if p = 0.5, Player 1 does not have a strict

incentive to change her strategy from q = 0.5.

 

Similarly, Player 2 does not have a strict incentive to

change his strategy from p = 0.5, if q = 0.5.

Therefore, p = q = 0.5 constitutes a mixed-strategy

equilibrium.

Q: Is this equilibrium reasonable/stable?

A: Yes (each player ends up randomizing two strategies

equally if the rival is smart enough).

(9)

Best Response Curves 

  Given the opponent mixed strategy, draw the best response (mixed strategy) against it.

p

1

BR2

BR1

0.5

NE

(10)

Existence of NE

Theorem (Nash, 1950)

 

If a game has finite number of players and actions,

then there exists at least one Nash equilibrium,

possibly involving mixed strategies.

 

Q: Are there any games which do not even have a

mixed-strategy equilibrium?

 

A: Yes. For example, integer game.

  (Two person) Zero-sum game in which players independently choose a number simultaneously. The player who picked a larger number wins.

(11)

Modified Matching Pennies 

 

Suppose the payoffs in the up-left cell changes as the

following:

Player 2 Player 1

Heads (p’) Tails (1-p’)

Heads (q’)

2 -2

-1 1

Tails -1 1

(12)

Indifference Property

  Under mixed-strategy NE, Player 1 must be indifferent between choosing H and T:

-2p’ + (1-p’) = p’ - (1-p’), hence p’ = 0.4.

  Similarly, Player 2 must be indifferent between choosing H and T:

2q’ - (1-q’) = -q’ + (1-q’), hence q’ = 0.4.

  You can easily verify that (p’, q’) = (0.4, 0.4) indeed becomes a mixed-strategy NE.

  Note that player 2 chooses H with less than a half chance, even if H looks “better” strategy than T.

(13)

Multiple Nash Equilibria 

2 1

D (x) E (y) F (1-x-y)

A (a)

6 7

8 5

0 0

B (b)

8 5

6 7

0 0

C 0 0 4

(14)

Three Different Equilibria 

  Pure-strategy NE

  (C, F) is a unique pure-strategy NE.

  Mixed-strategy NE (1)

  P1 mixes A (q) and B (1-q); p2 mixes D (p) and E (1-p).

  7p + 5(1-p) = 5p + 7(1-p) p = 1/2.

  6q + 8(1-q) = 8q + 6(1-q) q = 1/2.

  Mixed-strategy NE (2)

  Both players use all three strategies.

  A (a), B (b), C (1-a-b); D (x), E (y), F (1-x-y)

  7x + 5y = 5x + 7y = 4(1-x-y) x = y = 1/5.

(15)

Example in Business Competition (1) 

  R&D Race Game

  2 firms simultaneously decide the amount of investment

  Possible strategies are 0, 1, 2, (million dollars).

  The larger investment => Winner; receive 3 (as a revenue)

  The smaller investment => Loser; receive 0

  In the case of tie => both receive 1

  Is there any pure strategy NE?

  Derive mixed strategy NE.

(16)

Example in Business Competition (2) 

  Simultaneous Entry Game

  3 firms simultaneously choose entry decision.

  Possible strategies are enter (E) or not (N).

  If only 1 firm enter => profit is 4

  If 2 firms enter => profit is 1 each

  If all 3 firms enter => profit is -2 each

  Choosing N results in 0 profit.

  Is there any pure strategy NE?

  Are there multiple mixed strategy NE?

(17)

Example: Soccer (Penalty Kick) 

Kicker GK

Left (x) Middle (y) Right (1-x-y)

Left (p)

40 60

100 0

80 20

Middle (q)

80 20

0 100

80 20

Right 80 100 20

(18)

Further Exercises 

  Construct a game which has both pure-strategy and mixed-strategy Nash equilibria.

  Consider a modified matching penny game in which the payoff on (H, H) is changed from (-1, 1) to (-k, k) for k > 0. Then, derive a mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium.

  Prove that a strategy which is erased by the iterated

elimination of strictly dominated strategies can never be selected (with positive probability) in a mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium.

参照

関連したドキュメント

If, moreover, a and b are coprime and c is suffi- ciently large compared with a and b, then (1) has at most one solution. Diophantine equations, applications of linear forms in

For example, if we restrict to the class of closed, irreducible 3-manifolds, then as said above, each manifold has a bounded number of incompressible surfaces, but clearly there is

If the S n -equivariant count of points of this space, when considered as a function of the number of elements of the finite field, gives a polynomial, then using the purity we

In this paper, based on the concept of rough variable proposed by Liu 14, we discuss a simplest game, namely, the game in which the number of players is two and rough payoffs which

Also, if G has real rank at least 3, we provide a C ∞ classification for volume-preserving, multiplicity free, trellised, Anosov actions on compact

Using the theory of isometric actions on R -trees as a starting point, Sela has solved the isomorphism problem for hyperbolic groups (at least for torsion-free hyperbolic groups

In this section, we show a strong convergence theorem for finding a common element of the set of fixed points of a family of finitely nonexpansive mappings, the set of solutions

Theorem 1.2 If an n-manifold with compact (possibly empty) boundary is inward tame at innity, then it has nitely many ends, each of which has semistable fundamental group and