• 検索結果がありません。

Lec1 9 最近の更新履歴 yyasuda's website

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2017

シェア "Lec1 9 最近の更新履歴 yyasuda's website"

Copied!
14
0
0

読み込み中.... (全文を見る)

全文

(1)

Lecture 9: Firm Problem

Advanced Microeconomics I

Yosuke YASUDA

Osaka University, Department of Economics yasuda@econ.osaka-u.ac.jp

November 4, 2014

(2)

Production

Consumer theory imposes a strong structure on the choice sets (budget sets) but few constraints on the preferences or utility function. In contrast, classic producer theory assigns the producer a highly structured target function (profit function) but fewer constraints on the choice sets (technology or production functions).

Production is the process of transforming inputs into outputs. Let 1, ..., k be commodities. The producer’s choice will be made from subsets of the “grand set,” k-dimensional Euclidean space.

A vector z in this space is interpreted as a production combination; positive components in z are interpreted as outputs and negative components as inputs.

(Note that the firm’s profit can be expressed as pz=Pki=1pizi where p ∈ Rk++ is a vector of prices.)

2 / 14

(3)

Technology

Definition 1

A producer’s choice set is called a technology (or production possibility set), Z ⊂ Rk, which specifies the production constraints.

The following restrictions are usually placed on the technology Z:

1 0∈ Z: Producer can remain “idle.”

2 There is no z ∈ Z ∩ Rk+ besides the vector 0: No production with no resources.

3 If z ∈ Z and z ≤ z, then z ∈ Z: Free disposal.

4 Z is a convex set: Decreasing return to scale.

5 Z is a closed set.

Rm Check each restriction by drawing a figure with k = 2.

(4)

Production Function (1)

Suppose that a commodity (denoted by 0) is produced from other commodities 1, ..., n, that is, for all z ∈ Z, z0 ≥ 0 and zi ≤ 0 for i= 1, 2, ..., n.

Another way to describe the firm’s technological constraints is a production function, f : Rn+→ R+, which specifies, for any positive vector of inputs x ∈ Rn+, the maximum amount of commodity 0 that can be produced:

f(x) = max{y|(−x, y) ∈ Z}.

Theorem 2

When a function f satisfies the assumptions of (i) f (0) = 0, (ii) increasing, (iii) continuity, and (iv) concavity, then Z(f ) satisfies the above assumptions 1-5, where Z(f ) is defined as

Z(f ) = {(−x, y)| y ≤ y and x ≥ x for some y = f (x)}.

4 / 14

(5)

Production Function (2)

Q A production function f (x) is said to be

1 Constant returns to scale (homogeneous of degree 1): if f (tx) = tf (x) for all t > 0 and all x.

2 Increasing returns to scale:

if f (tx) > tf (x) for all t > 1 and all x.

3 Decreasing returns to scale:

if f (tx) < tf (x) for all t > 1 and all x. Theorem 3

Suppose that the production function f (x) satisfies (i) f (0) = 0, (ii) increasing, (iii) continuity, and (iv’) quasi-concavity, and constant returns to scale. Then it is a (iv) concave function.

(6)

Cost function (1)

Let w = (w1, ..., wn) ≥ 0 be a vector of prevailing market prices at which the firm can buy inputs (x1, ..., xn).

Definition 4

The cost function is the minimum-value function of the following cost minimization problem,

c(w, y) =: min

x∈Rn+

wx s.t. f (x) ≥ y.

Mathematically speaking, the cost function is identical to the expenditure function.

e(p, u) =: min

x∈Rn+

px s.t. u(x) ≥ u.

So, the properties that the expenditure function e(·) possesses also hold for the cost function c(·).

6 / 14

(7)

Cost function (2)

Theorem 5

If f is continuous, strictly increasing and f (0) = 0, then the cost function c(w, y) : Rn+1+ → R+ is

1 Zero when y = 0.

2 Continuous on its domain.

3 For all w≫ 0, strictly increasing and unbounded above in y.

4 Increasing in w.

5 Homogeneous of degree one in w.

6 Concave in w.

Moreover, if f is strictly quasi-concave we have

7 Shephard’s lemma: c(w, y) is differentiable in w at (w0, y0) whenever w≫ 0, and

∂c(w0, y0)

∂wi

= xi(w0, y0), i = 1, ..., n.

(8)

Firm’s Objectives

We assume the goal of the firm (producer) is to maximize profits.

Q Why is the producer’s goal “profit maximization”?

(Only) Profit maximizing firms would survive in the long-run under competitive pressure.

Profit maximization is the single most robust and compelling assumption. (JR, pp.125)

Just for mathematical convenience? (Rubinstein, Lecture 7)

Ex Alternative plausible(?) targets:

Increase market share subject to not incurring a loss. Increase salaries with less regard for the level of profits.

8 / 14

(9)

Cost minimization (1)

If the object of the firm is to maximize profits, it will necessarily choose the least costly production plan for every level of output. (Note this must be true for all profit-maximizing firms, whether monopolists, perfect competitors, or anything between.)

min

x∈Rn+

wx s.t. f (x) ≥ y.

Assuming x ≫ 0 and solve this problem by Lagrange’s method. (Note f (x) = y must be satisfied at the optimal solution.)

L = wx − λ(f (x) − y).

∂L

∂xi = wi− λ

∂f(x)

∂xi = 0 for i = 1, ..., n.

∂L

∂λ = f (x) − y = 0.

(10)

Cost minimization (2)

From the first order conditions, we obtain

∂f(x)

∂xi

∂f(x)

∂xj

= wi

wj for any i, j.

Cost minimization implies that the marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS) between any two inputs is equal to the ratio of their prices.

Definition 6

The solution x(w, y) is referred to as the firm’s conditional (contingent) input demand, because it is conditional on the level of output y, which at this point is arbitrary and so may or may not be a profit maximizing.

10 / 14

(11)

Profit Maximization (1)

Suppose the competitive firm can sell each unit of output at the market price, p. There are two different ways to solve the firm’s profit maximization problem.

One-step procedure: max

x∈Rn+

py− wx s.t. f (x) ≥ y

which is equivalent to (since f (x) = y must hold) P M1 : max

x∈Rn+

pf(x) − wx.

Two-step procedure: P M2 : max

y≥0 py− c(w, y).

(12)

Profit Maximization (2)

Rm It can be shown that the P M 1 and P M2 are equivalent. Assuming x ≫ 0, P M1 is just an unconstrained problem with

“multiple” variables. So we can solve it by just taking partial derivatives.

∂[pf (x) − wx]

∂xi

= p∂f(x

)

∂xi

− wi = 0 for i = 1, ..., n.

From the first order conditions, we obtain

∂f(x)

∂xi

∂f(x)

∂xj

= wi wj

for any i, j.

This is precisely the same as the condition for cost minimization input choice. It therefore confirms our earlier intuition that profit maximization “requires” cost minimization in production.

12 / 14

(13)

Profit Maximization (3)

Definition 7

The optimal choice of inputs x= x(p, w) gives the vector of input demand functions. (Note these input demands are no longer “conditional” since they are independent of output.) Assuming y >0, P M2 is just an unconstrained problem with

“one” variable: d[py − c(w, y)]

dy = p −

dc(w, y)

dy = 0.

Therefore, output is chosen so that “price equals marginal cost”. Definition 8

The optimal choice of output y = y(p, w) is called the firm’s (output) supply function. The maximum-value function, denoted by π(p, w), is called the profit function.

π(p, w) =: maxnpf(x) − wx.

(14)

Profit Maximization (4)

Theorem 9

Suppose f is continuous, strictly increasing, strictly quasi-concave, and f (0) = 0. Then, for p ≥ 0 and w ≥ 0, π(p, w), where

well-defined, is continuous and

1 Increasing in p.

2 Decreasing in w.

3 Homogeneous of degree one in (p, w).

4 Convex in (p, w).

5 Differentiable in (p, w) ≫ 0. Moreover, ( Hotelling’s lemma),

∂π(p, w)

∂p = y(p, w) and −∂π(p, w)

∂wi

= xi(p, w), i = 1, ..., n.

Rm Note that profit maximization problem is mathematically not identical to utility maximization problem.

14 / 14

参照

関連したドキュメント

In particular, Theorem 2.1 can be used to solve the inverse problem of approximation theory of functions that are continuous on a uniformly perfect compact subset of the real line

As with subword order, the M¨obius function for compositions is given by a signed sum over normal embeddings, although here the sign of a normal embedding depends on the

Most papers on economic growth considering the Solow-Swan or neoclassical model used the Cobb-Douglas specification of the production function, which describes a process with a

Keywords: nonparametric regression; α-mixing dependence; adaptive estima- tion; wavelet methods; rates of convergence.. Classification:

Making use, from the preceding paper, of the affirmative solution of the Spectral Conjecture, it is shown here that the general boundaries, of the minimal Gerschgorin sets for

– proper &amp; smooth base change ← not the “point” of the proof – each commutative diagram → Ð ÐÐÐ... In some sense, the “point” of the proof was to establish the

– Solvability of the initial boundary value problem with time derivative in the conjugation condition for a second order parabolic equation in a weighted H¨older function space,

Guo, “A class of logarithmically completely monotonic functions and the best bounds in the second Kershaw’s double inequality,” Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics,