• 検索結果がありません。

The Price Decline of Rice and its Effects on the Family Farm : A Case Study of the Tohoku Region

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

シェア "The Price Decline of Rice and its Effects on the Family Farm : A Case Study of the Tohoku Region"

Copied!
15
0
0

読み込み中.... (全文を見る)

全文

(1)

The Price Decline of Rice and its Effects on

the Family Farm : A Case Study of the Tohoku

Region

著者

SASAKI Toru

雑誌名

The science reports of the Tohoku University.

7th series, Geography

56

1

ページ

35-48

発行年

2009-03

URL

http://hdl.handle.net/10097/45272

(2)

35

The Price Decline of

: A Case

Rice and its

Study of the

Effects on the Family

Tohoku Region

Farm

Toru SASAKI*

Abstract The price of rice has declined rapidly since 1995. The response has been to restructure Japanese agriculture not by increasing the size of farms but by diversifying farming management with labor-intensive crops. The depen-dence on rice to secure agricultural income is still high in the Tohoku region, and thus the price decline for rice has directly decreased agricultural income in the area. The plan for restructuring farm management in the Tohoku region is the same as that on the national scale, that is, converting rice monoculture farms to diversified management. However, much of the Tohoku region grows rice as the main crop of diversification. Further decreases in the price of rice will have a negative impact on these farms.

Key words : price decline of rice, rice monoculture

Tohoku region, Japanese agriculture

farm, diversified farm,

1. Introduction

Since the mid 1990s, The World Trade Organization (WTO)'s globalization has

affected Japanese agriculture. A series of trade liberalization policies rapidly

increases agricultural imports and decreased the price of domestic agricultural

prod-ucts. Thus, the liberalization resulting from the WTO's globalization forcibly reduced Japan's agricultural production.

The decline of Japanese agriculture is obvious ; the gross domestic product (GDP) share of agriculture decreased from 9% in 1960 to 1.6% in 2005. Similarly, both the

number of farm households and the acreage of cultivated farmlands decreased. From

1985 to 2005, the number of farm households decreased 35%, while farmlands decreased

20%. At the same time, agricultural output decreased about 24% from 11,540 billion

yen in 1985, the peak year, to 880 billion yen in 2005.

This declining and restructuring tendency has progressed swiftly because of the

decline in the price of rice. Although rice plays a key role in Japanese agriculture, the share of rice to agricultural output decreased from 32% in 1985 to 23% in 2005. On

Graduate Student, Institute of Geography, Graduate of School of Science, Tohoku University, Sendai 980-8578, Japan

(3)

36 Toru SASAKI

the other hand, that of vegetables and livestock increased. Thus, various kinds of

crops other than rice became key crops in Japanese agriculture. After the new Food Law of 1995 became effective to replace the Food Control Law of 1942, the price of rice

began to drop rapidly, decreasing agricultural income and damaging the income of

farm households.

Such a policy shift directs the trend of agricultural reorganization. This phenom-enon becomes interesting because it has been regarded as a serious structural problem

and an objective of policy research. In particular, Hokkaido, Tohoku and Hokuriku

are studied as regions of interest. Those areas are also representative rice production

regions in Japan. The main concern of these regions is clarifying formation or

development factors of competitive large-scale rice farming management.

There-fore, in this context, I believe that the following two problems must be addressed as a part of the significant subject of agricultural reorganization.

First, in the past, scholars were attracted only to the studies of scale expansion as farmers reacted to the price decline of rice. However, scale expansion at the single

management level is not the only possible reaction ; management diversification is

another option. While many Japanese farms depend on a family labor force (Isobe,

2000), farm households tend to diversify their managements with their farm size

increased (Hirabayashi, 2007). Therefore, when analyzing the diversified farm, one

must simultaneously examine both the trend toward large-scale management and the

direction of agricultural reorganization.

Second, in light of the examination of diversified farms as a possible direction of

agricultural reorganization, the conditions for selecting appropriate crops must be

examined. Currently, there are few studies about diversified farms (Yamadera, Arai,

2003). The past research clarifies that farmers have most often tried to choose

profitable crops to advance diversification instead of expanding the scale of rice

farming. However, in the situation of intense market competition with the increase

of agricultural imports, farmers' capacity to choose alternative crops is considerably

narrowed (Higashiyama, 2001). Therefore, to establish marketable crops, it is

neces-sary for an agricultural production area to attain a certain scale of operation and profitability. In the end, I would like to show how scale expansion and management diversification affect the characteristics of Japanese agriculture.

In this paper, I clarify how the price decline of rice has changed farm

manage-ments in the Tohoku region. For this purpose, I analyze forms of farm management

on a national scale. In the second section of the paper, I explore the regional

characteristics of Japanese agriculture, including a look at the trends of agricultural sale, scale enlargement, and the number of days of input labor. Next, I explore the effects of rice price decline in the Tohoku region, which very much depends on rice. For this purpose, I describe the characteristics and changes in Tohoku's agricultural

(4)

The Price Decline of Rice and its Effects on the Family Farm 37

regions that have occurred during the last decade.

2. The Rice Price Decl ine and Development of Japan's Agricultural Regions

Figure 1 shows the price trends of main varieties of rice in recent years. The data for 1993, a year of severe cold-weather damage, has been removed from the chart ; the highest prices for all rice brands occurred in 1992. After the Food Control Law was abandoned in 1995, the price of all brands began a downward trend. Even the price of Koshihikari in Niigata decreased about 30% from 25,429 yen in 1992 to 19,176 yen in 2002. This is supposed to be the most expensive rice in Japan. This tendency is seen in every rice brand and affects most severely those regions expecting high prices for rice.

Figure 2 shows the distribution of part-time farms and rice monoculture farms in

Japan in 2005. This figure shows the relational nature between farms dependent on

rice production and part-time farming. First, regarding rice monoculture farms,

while 52.3% is the national average, a higher proportion of these farms is distributed

from Tohoku to Hokuriku. Toyama (91.5%) has the greatest proportion of rice

monoculture farms, followed by Niigata (87.1%). Akita (81.4%) has the greatest

proportion of these farms in the Tohoku region. In contrast, Hokkaido, Tokai,

Y e n 6 0 k g 28, 000 26, 000 24, 000 22, 000 --*—Kirara397 (Hokkaido) (Miyagi) —0—Hi tomebore (Miyagi) —D—Akitakomachi (Aklita) --*—Koshihikari (Nigata) 20, 000 18, 000 16, 000 14, 000 12, 000 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Year

Figure 1 The price of major rice varieties through years source : Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries

(5)

38 Torn SASAKI

Rice monoculture farm (%) 11175 - 100 (7) E 50 - 75 (18) 25 - 50 (13) n 0 25 (9)

Type of farm

(%)

11)

BM

Full-time

farm

n

Part-time

farm

oso

• : • :( ° • : . . .

' : 11:111P

Cr

4rif

N r=s, • •\

_41.

i

5 Figure 2 Source 0

W+E

150 300 I I I km

The proportion of part-time farms and rice monoculture farms in Japan in 2005 Agricultural Census

Shikoku, and Kyushu have the lowest proportion of rice monoculture farms.

In terms of part-time farms, the national average is 77.4%, indicating that part-time farms continue to play a central role in Japanese agriculture. However, in the

matter of regional differences, the number of part-time farms in Tohoku and

Hoku-riku is relatively high, while the number in Tokai, Shikoku, and Kyushu is low. The

proportion of part-time farms is the highest in Fukui (90.3%) and the lowest in

Hokkaido (47.8%).

These statistics show that areas tend to have both a high proportion of rice

monoculture farms and a high proportion of part-time farms, which indicates that

mechanization and laborsaving practices for rice production created part-time

farm-ing. On the other hand, under the price decline of rice, many part-time farmers are

still involved in rice farming. They are very likely to be engaged only in rice

monoculture.

(6)

The Price Decline of Rice and its Effects on the Family Farm 39

84%, 81.7% (in 2000) to 77.4%, and the proportion of rice monoculture farms also

decreased from 55.2%, 54.2% to 53.2%. This is attributed to the decreasing number

of rice monoculture farms and the increase of elderly full-time farmers. The elderly in the countryside retire from other industries and begin to work full-time on their farms.

The number of farm households decreased to fewer than 2 million households by

2005 as the economic status of rice fell. However, according to Ando (2001), some

farmers have attempted to farm full-time to diversify management while not carrying out the scale enlargement of rice farming.

Figure 3 shows the makeup of farms with regard to size and crop. This figure

shows the effect of scale enlargement on agricultural sales. Prefectural dependence

18 Rice monoculture farm

0-30% - 16 •45 Groupl 030 ^50% A50-70% 023 043 x70%- 14 >-.

5 12

039 • 22

•10

Group2

• 14 412 10 0 41 • 30 •42 0a0 • 46 °9 8 A 8, a o 36 020 7,7 A 6 S a ° 011 el3 4 1 9•A21 4 027 A-A 6,31 el3 0 1 1 7 ,„, )<)' 3 4 1 9•A29 027 A 21 ,r / 44 6 7 x) 3 4 •382x 17 1516x24 x 5 2 378.z A32 33 x25 Ax 34 A 35 x18x 16 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Farms with more than 5ha (%)

Figure 3 Scale enlargement and farm income in 2005 Source: Agricultural Census

2. Aomori 3. Iwate 4. Miyagi 5. Akita 6. Yamagata 7. Fukusima 8. Ibaraki 9. Tochigi 10. Gunma 11. Saitama 12. Chiba 13. Tokyo

14. Kanagawa 15. Nigata 16. Toyama 17. Ishikawa 18. Fukui

19. Yamanashi 20. Nagano 21. Gifu 22. Sizuoka 23. Aichi 24. Mie 25. Shiga 26. Kyoto 27. Osaka 28. Hyogo 29. Nara 30. Wakayama

31. Tottori 32. Sihimane 33. Okayama 34. Hiroshima 35. Yamaguchi

36. Tokushima 37. Kagawa 38. Ehime 39. Kochi 40. Fukuoka 41. Saga 42. Ngasaki 43. Kumamoto 44. Oita 45. Miyazaki 46. Nagasaki

(7)

40 Toru SASAKI

on rice is also shown as the attributes of each prefecture except Hokkaido are

indicated, based on the proportion of farms devoted to rice monoculture. The vertical axis shows the proportion of farmers who sell more than 10 million yen in agricultural products ; the horizontal axis shows the proportion of farmers who have more than 5 ha of farmlands. This shows the trend of Ninaite. Ninaite is a Japanese policy term

for a designated competitive farm. These farms are supposed to earn high income as

they increase the economic efficiency with scale enlargement.

Two groups are found in the figure. In Group 1, the proportion of farms with more than 5 ha of farmlands is higher than the national average. In this group, the farmers try to earn agricultural income by growing rice. In Group 2, the proportion of farms with more than 10 million yen in sales is higher than the national average. These farmers tend not to conduct scale enlargement of rice farming and secure their agricultural income from rice sales.

These groups demonstrate the following regional differences. Tohoku,

Hokuri-ku, and Chugoku belong to Group 1. As the proportion of rice monoculture farms is

high, the dominant farms tend to be formed to grow land-intensive crops. Yamagata

(No. 6) and Akita (No. 5), for example, have large-scale rice farms. The Kanto,

Shikoku, and Kyushu regions belong to Group 2. In some parts of these regions, as the proportion of rice monoculture farms is low, the dominant farms tend to be formed to grow crops other than rice ; for example, in Miyazaki (No. 45), Kochi (No. 39), and

Aichi (No. 23), labor-intensive agriculture like greenhouse gardening exists. Thus,

the regional composition of present Japanese agriculture is divided into two different

management types. However, this regional distinction of Japanese agriculture does

not explain the positive relation between scale enlargement and agricultural sale.

Rather, the introduction and expansion of labor-intensive agriculture like greenhouse

gardening has diversified farm management and increased farm incomes. That is,

scale enlargement of land-intensive farming does not necessarily result in high profit.

Figure 4 supports the high profitability of introducing labor-intensive crops in

diversified farming. The vertical axis shows the proportion of farmers who sell more than 10 million yen in agricultural products ; the horizontal axis shows the proportion of farmers who have over 900 days of labor input. The attributes of each prefecture are shaded by the proportion of farms in which more than two crop types are managed. As the figure shows, the addition of a crop type, which can increase labor input, leads to increased income. One example is the introduction of horticulture in diversified management.

The area of Group 2 is shown in Figure 3. Miyazaki (No. 45), Kumamoto (No.

43), and Kochi (No. 39) are in the upper right corner, while Iwate (No. 3), Akita (No. 4), Miyagi (No. 5), Niigata (No. 15), Toyama (No. 16), and Fukui (No. 18) are dis-tributed in the lower left part of the figure. The former three and the latter three

(8)

The Price Decline of Rice and its Effects on the Family Farm 41 18 16 14 0

8

12 10 22, 8 0 8 6 4 2 0

Over two sections farm • 50 040-50% A 30 ---4096 X ----30% 25A 15 X 4 2,9 17 X

5X24,9

32 A28 37 460 06 O2

4k/S---47

< ,.,9 0 3 31A A 6`18 27 41

t9

A 8 A 11 •40 0 36 • 10 022 12,6 43DA 30 02

61631,32--

35 6 8 10 oner 900 days to input labor(%)

• 13 • 45 436D 23 0 14 R2 = 0.8065 039 0 2 4 Farm of 12 14

Figure 4 Farms with over 900 days of input labor shown according to farm income in 2005

Source : Agricultural Census

belong to Tohoku and Hokuriku regions, respectively.

Unfortunately, the alternative farm development strategy to the scale expansion

of rice farms faces a difficult situation. That is, the selection and concentration of

competitive farms didn't form competitive farm regions, and the number of

competi-tive farms decreased. Farmers with more than 10 million yen in sales decreased from

128,000 in 1995 to 116,000 in 2005, while the proportion of these farmers to the total number of farmers remained almost the same, rising only ca. 1% from 5.0% to 6.1%. The same logic works in terms of large-scale farms. While the number of farms with more than 5 ha increased from 35,000 households to 50,000 households, the proportion

of these farms only increased 1.6% from 1.0% to 2.6%. Thus, the prospect of

diversified farming is not so positive, either. This problem has occurred with labor-intensive crops such as vegetables and flowers ; for example, the competition with imported agricultural products slowed the increase in price. The lack of a dependable workforce in the agricultural sector and the obstacles resulting from repeated planting are also factors.

Table 1 shows the reduction rate of farms and cultivated land from 1995 to 2005.

The average national reduction in farms was 17.0%, and that of cultivated land was

(9)

42 Toru SASAKI

Table 1 Decreases in agricultural resources in Japan, 1995-2005

1995-2005 Hokkaido Tohoku Hokuriku Kanto Tokai Kinki Tyugoku Sikoku Kyusyu Average Farm decrease 27.0 16.5 20.5 16.3 15.7 16.4 18.8 15.7 16.9 17.2 Farmland decrease 5.5 13.2 18.1 21.4 26.1 23.7 29.0 27.5 17.9 16.3 source : Agricultural Census

the national average in farm reduction. Hokuriku (18.1%), Kanto (21.4%), Tokai

(26.1%), Kinki (23.7%), Chugoku (29.0%), Shikoku (27.5%), and Kyushu (17.9%)

showed a higher pace of decrease in cultivated farmland than the national average.

In the Hokkaido, Tohoku, and Hokuriku regions, the pace of decrease in

culti-vated land was slower than the pace of decrease in farms. While farms and cultivated land decreased, the scale expansion of individual farms was not fast enough to enable the cultivation of depreciated farmland.

In other areas, however, the proportion of cultivated land decreased more than

20%. The reduction is especially remarkable in the Pacific coastal zone. This is

probably because not only the reduction of farms but also the conversion to

non-agricultural land use and the abandonment of cultivated farmland have affected this

area. As a result, while the size of the labor force and the means of production continue to decrease in Japanese agriculture.

3. Changes in the Agricultural Areas of the Tohoku Region

3.1 Changes in the Farm Household Economy in the Tohoku Region

As discussed above, the recent rice price decline did not increase the size of many Japanese farms but it did cause a diversification of management with labor-intensive crops. In this section, I would like to consider how the rice price decline has affected

the Tohoku Region. Tohoku is normally considered to have a high level of rice

dependence.

First of all, in terms of Tohoku's position within Japan, the region's proportion of

the total domestic agricultural production decreased from 18% to 16%. However,

(10)

The Price Decline of Rice and its Effects on the Family Farm 43

2005, Tohoku had 26% of the nation's rice growing area and 26% of the national rice

production. Tohoku also produces 70% of domestically produced apples and 80% of

domestic cherries. In terms of feeding heads in livestock, Tohoku's share of beef

cattle is 17% ; that of hogs is 16% ; that of broiler chickens is 22%. However, agricultural output in the Tohoku region decreased 34% from 254 billion yen in 1985 to 138 billion yen in 2005. Particularly, rice output decreased by half from 100 billion yen to 50 billion yen. Thus the declining position of Tohoku in the nation seems to result from the rice price decline and its negative effect on rice output.

While rice mainly characterizes regional agriculture of the Tohoku region, the

Tohoku farmers have changed the nature of the farm household economy in several

ways. Figure 5 shows the basic indexes of the farm household economy from 1965 to

2003. Living expenditure consistently increased to 1998. It increased from 600,000

yen in 1965, 1 million yen in 1969, 2 million yen in 1975, 3 million yen in 1977, 4 million yen in 1980, and 5 million yen in 1991 to 5.6 million yen in 1998. Since then, it has fluctuated from 5 to 6 million yen. In 2003, it was 5.06 million yen. On the other hand,

agricultural gross income was below living expenditures from 1969. The gap

in-creased every year, reaching 1.67 million yen in 2003. Unfortunately, as agricultural expenditures increased even in the 2000s, the ratio of agricultural income to family

8000 7000 6000 5000 0 cg 4000 3000 2000 1000 0 • • - ./.1\

xja,71)

-\ /1 • ^-EL .cr cr 13 El. C. .0 P. - , .o-t r. Er 1:1 • 0. 0 80 70 60 50 40 % 30 20 10 0 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000

—0—Agricultural gross income 0 Agricultural expenditure

-- - -Agricultural income —A— Non-agricultural income

- Total income of farm household ^ Living expenditure

-A- Ratio of agricultural income to family expenditure - -U- Dependent ratio on agriculture

Figure 5 Farm household economy in Tohoku

(11)

44 Toru SASAKI

expenditure decreased to about 20%. The total income of farm households increased

from 1965 to 1995. It was 77,000 yen in 1965 ; more than 1 million yen in 1967 ; more than 2 million yen in 1973 ; 3 million yen in 1975 ; 4 million yen in 1979 ; 5 million yen in 1985 ; 6 million yen in 1990 ; 6.7 million yen in 1994. However, since 1995, the total income has decreased at an unprecedented pace. Reaching 5.13 million yen in 2003, it decreased to the same level as family expenditure. The decrease of farm income from 1995 is attributed to the rice price decline after the abandonment of the Food Control

Law. Owing to the high dependence on rice in Tohoku's farm household economy, the

direct impact of the rice price decline becomes highly significant. In addition,

non-agricultural income decreased from the peak of 5.29 million yen in 1997. This was

another cause of the decrease in the total income of farm households, because non-agricultural income played a significant role to sustain the total income. In 2003, non-agricultural income decreases to 4 million yen ; this is the same as in 1988.

In the 1990s, non-agricultural income decreased because the dislocation of rural

factories shrank the regional labor market. As a consequence, while the dependence

on agriculture increased slightly, the farm household economy generally continued to

deteriorate.

3.2 Regional Characteristics of Tohoku Agriculture

The classification of regions by agricultural sale leads to the analysis of regional characteristics as a way of understanding the characteristics of rice production in the Tohoku region. Figure 6 shows the classification of regions within the Tohoku region.

4 1\2.= ./

2:AI

• 16 • ,;,.. ..,.„58nk 7^ x 17 •100 lx . 2• n

itpx 15

0

C220k-14

23 • /24010 25 a • a 3, 500 3, 000 2, 500 2, 000 06 1, 500 - 0 8 1, 000 05 03 500 0 — Reigion types •Rice–dependence

°Upland cropping and livestock div, L.Fruit div. ^Livestock X Others •21 02 0 7 Tclhoku A 0 13 Aty 6 • 222.. . .. _ .. •20- P024 91 025 0p•16 to 12 118 • 23 X1 X 15 0 20 • 17 30 40 50 60 70 80 Rice–dependence (%)

Figure 6 Rice-dependence and agricultural income in Tohoku (2005)

(12)

The Price Decline of Rice and its Effects on the Family Farm 45

The vertical axis represents agricultural income per farm ; the horizontal axis repre-sents the share of rice to agricultural output (the value of rice-dependence in this study). These regions are historically organized according to their regional economic

centers. Furthermore, based on the makeup of agricultural output, these regions are

grouped into five types. The first type is a rice-dependence region, because rice

consists of more than 50% of agricultural output in this region. This region type is shown with a black circle.

The second type is a region with diversified agriculture with upland cropping and livestock. In this type of region, rice consists of less than 50% of the agricultural output, while the rate of upland cropping and livestock is more than the average of the Tohoku region. This region type is shown with a white circle. The third type is a region with diversified agriculture with fruit. In this type of region, rice consists of less than 50% of the region's agricultural output, while the ratio of fruit to agricultural output is more than the average of the Tohoku region. This region type is shown in a triangle in the figure. The fourth type is a livestock region, in which livestock accounts for more than 50% of the agricultural output. This region type is shown in

a rectangular. The other regions are shown in a crosshair. These are not

significantly grouped like the other region types.

Usami (1985) points out that these regional characteristics emerge because of the

unique historical experience of agriculture in Tohoku. That is, No. 5 to 8 were

regarded as an area with upland crops and horse-raising in the Meiji period. No. 3 and No. 19 were regarded as an area with rice farming and sericulture in the Meiji period. After WWII, this type of region produced fruit instead of silkworms. No. 2, No. 13, No. 18, No. 21, and No. 23 established a region with powerful landlords before the war. After the war, this type of region became a region with rice monoculture.

With the current rice price decline, the characteristics of the Tohoku region reflect the history of each region. The characteristics express two directions, as exemplified by Group 1 and Group 2. In Group 1, agricultural income increases as rice-dependence increases ; for example, No. 17 and No. 21 have the greatest income in the group.

They are a representative region of large-scale rice production, and their success

indicates that rice production can allow a region to secure agricultural income even under a rice price decline.

On the other hand, in Group 2, agricultural income increases as rice-dependence

decreases. No. 5 and No. 6 are the most successful examples in this group. These

are large producers of vegetable such as garlic and Chinese yams. No. 3 is a large

producer of apples. These regions show a successful way to secure income by

establishing the production of vegetables and fruits. They diversify farm

manage-ment with crops other than rice.

(13)

46 Toru SASAKI

importance of rice remains. The share of rice to agricultural output in Tohoku is

38%, that is, 15% higher than 23%, the national average. However, as shown in

Figure. 6, the fact is that regions have higher agricultural income if they have crops other than rice as their main crops.

The impact of the rice price decline is considered in Figure 7, where a comparison between 1995 and 2005 shows the change in each region. All regions but No. 5 and No.

17 show a decreased agricultural income. Moreover, all regions except No. 17 show

both a decreased degree of rice-dependence and decreased agricultural income. The

rice price decline can directly decrease agricultural income. This tendency was more significant in regions with 50% to 60% rice dependence in 1995. These regions show the importance of rice in the Tohoku region.

Each type of region reacts differently to the decreases in rice-dependence and

agricultural income. The rice-dependent regions have decreased their dependence by

about 8%, while the decreasing rate of agricultural income is more than 18% in these regions. That is, regions highly affected by the rice price decrease cannot easily stop

depending on the rice monoculture. Regions with diversified agriculture with upland

cropping and livestock have decreased their dependence on rice by about 10%. The share of rice there is 37% of the agricultural output. These regions have softened the

a) CD CD a:3 4. a) a) 0 0 0 c.) s-, 3500 3000 2500 2000 1500 1000 500 0 19 5

78

3 7 oI 24 22

((0 •

10 9 25

c()D/11

/15

•1995 02005 2 21 0 --Of320

(1,23

17 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 Rice—dependence(%)

Figure 7 Changes of agricultural regions under rice price decline Source: Annul Agricultural income products Census

(14)

The Price Decline of Rice and its Effects on the Family Farm 47

impact of the rice price decline as they changed crops from rice or diversified their

management. In regions with diversified agriculture with fruit and in livestock

regions, although the rate of rice-dependence has decreased to 41%, the agricultural

income has decreased 28%. Fruit and livestock, the main products of these regions,

made the difference. Also, the competition with other domestic production regions

has become more intense. In these regions, the dynamics of non-rice products can

negatively affect farm management. In this way, the rice price decline has affected the agricultural regions in Tohoku in a variety of ways.

Currently, the Tohoku region faces a big problem. Not only does it have a low selection of crop varieties from which to choose, but the conditions for rice production are eroding. As a result, the region cannot change crop types. They only face the

rapid decline of rice price. The problem becomes more immediate to restructure

regional agriculture. The region needs to break away from rice monoculture

part-time farming, while the conversion of management becomes indispensable for farm

households to survive under the ongoing rice price decline.

4. Conclusion

In this study I examined the directions of farmers under an ongoing rice price decline in Japan. As a result, the following points become clear.

1) The price of rice has declined rapidly since 1995. While some agricultural regions have both a high proportion of rice monoculture farms and a high proportion

of part-time farms, both part-time farms and rice monoculture farms are decreasing

in proportion and number on the national scale. In this situation, the direction to restructure Japanese agriculture and farmers is not to increase the size of farms but

to diversify farm management with labor-intensive crops. In the regions with

depen-dence on rice production, the effects of enlargement of farm size were limited. A

decline in the price of rice does not necessarily increase agricultural sales and farm

income when regions increase farm size. In the meantime, growing crops other than

rice is difficult because the number of farmers with more than 1,000,000 yen in

agricultural sales has decreased.

2) The dependence on rice is still high in the Tohoku region. Rice production continues to be important to assure agricultural income. Thus, the rice price decline

has directly decreased agricultural income in an obvious way. Furthermore, since

1995, the rate of farm income decrease has been more acute than ever. Agricultural

management costs and living expenditures have also increased. At the same time,

non-agricultural income has decreased, while this income is needed to sustain the farm

income. The direction of farm management restructuring in the Tohoku region is the

(15)

48 Toru SASAKI

to diversified management. However, many farmers in the Tohoku region already have rice as the main crop of diversification, so a further rice price decline may decrease the number of farms. While this provides the opportunity to increase farm size, the possibility is thin at the current price of rice.

Acknowledgements

My deepest appreciation goes to Prof. M. Hino, whose suggestions were of inestimable value for

my study. I am indebted to Prof. T. Koganezawa, whose comments contributed enormously to my

work. I wish to express my gratitude also to my friend, Mr. Yoshitaka Miyake, who edited the

English.

References (* in Japanese, ** in Japanese with English abstract)

Ando, M. (2001) : rAtarashii jyousounou _i to inasaku seisannryoku kouzou*. Nougyo mondai kenkyu 50, 9-20.

Higashiyama, K. (2006) : Touhoku-chiiki ni okeru fukugougata-syuraku-einou no kai*, Hirano, N : Higashi-nihon no kyousei nougyo shisutemu. Nourin-toukei-kyoukai,

45-81.

Hirabayashi, M. (2007) : Daikibo-kazoku-keiei no tennkai-kouzou to sono youin Touhoku suiden-saku chitai yamagata, syounai* : Kajii, I : Nougyo kouzou-kaikaku no

kai. Nihon nougyo nenpou 53.

Hirano, N. (2006) : Kokusou-chitai toshiteno Touhoku • Hokuriku*, Hirano, N : Higashi -nilum no kyousei nougyo shisutemu. Nourin-toukei-kyoukai, 1-16.

Isobe, H. (2000) : Commune no sisou.* Nihonkeizai-hyouronsya, Tokyo.

Nakamura, K. (2006): Tohoku-Syounai nioru chiiki-nougyo-saihen no tokusitu to kyousei kouzou*. Hirano, N : Tohoku- nihon-kokusou-chitai no kyousei nougyo system.

in-toukei-kyokai, 82-117.

Nakamura, K. (2006) : Jirituteki- chiiki-nougyo-saihen no kouzo— tayou na chiiki *whit soshiki no governance—*. Nousei-tyousa-iinnkai.

Usami, S. (1985): Michinoku karano Nougyo Saikousei. Niho-keizai-hyouronsya, Tokyo. Usami, S. (2005) : Nougyo-seisanryoku-tenkai to Chitaikousei*. Tsukuba-syobou, Tokyo. Yamadera, S. and Arai, S. (2003) : Kome seisaku tenkanki niokeru Niigata-ken chu-jyousou

nouka no keiei senryaku, kita-kanbara-gun nakajou-machi wo jirei ni. chiri-kagaku 58, 22-45.

Figure  1  The  price  of  major  rice  varieties  through  years  source   :  Ministry  of  Agriculture,  Forestry  and  Fisheries
Figure  3  shows  the  makeup  of  farms  with  regard  to  size  and  crop.  This  figure  shows  the  effect  of  scale  enlargement  on  agricultural  sales
Figure  4  Farms  with  over  900  days  of  input  labor  shown  according  to  farm  income  in  2005  Source   :  Agricultural  Census
Table  1  Decreases  in  agricultural  resources  in  Japan,  1995-2005
+3

参照

関連したドキュメント

[11] Karsai J., On the asymptotic behaviour of solution of second order linear differential equations with small damping, Acta Math. 61

Keywords: continuous time random walk, Brownian motion, collision time, skew Young tableaux, tandem queue.. AMS 2000 Subject Classification: Primary:

We present sufficient conditions for the existence of solutions to Neu- mann and periodic boundary-value problems for some class of quasilinear ordinary differential equations.. We

Answering a question of de la Harpe and Bridson in the Kourovka Notebook, we build the explicit embeddings of the additive group of rational numbers Q in a finitely generated group

Then it follows immediately from a suitable version of “Hensel’s Lemma” [cf., e.g., the argument of [4], Lemma 2.1] that S may be obtained, as the notation suggests, as the m A

Definition An embeddable tiled surface is a tiled surface which is actually achieved as the graph of singular leaves of some embedded orientable surface with closed braid

We give a Dehn–Nielsen type theorem for the homology cobordism group of homol- ogy cylinders by considering its action on the acyclic closure, which was defined by Levine in [12]

Our method of proof can also be used to recover the rational homotopy of L K(2) S 0 as well as the chromatic splitting conjecture at primes p &gt; 3 [16]; we only need to use the