• 検索結果がありません。

PS2 Solution 最近の更新履歴 yyasuda's website

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2017

シェア "PS2 Solution 最近の更新履歴 yyasuda's website"

Copied!
5
0
0

読み込み中.... (全文を見る)

全文

(1)

Eco 600E Advanced Microeconomics I Term: Spring (1st), 2009

Lecturer: Yosuke Yasuda

Problem Set 2: Solution Due in class on June 4

1. Question 1 (15 points)

Suppose the utility function u(x) is continuous and strictly increasing. Then, prove the following properties of the indirect utility function v(p; !):

(a) Strictly increasing in !. Answer:

Let x 2 B(p; !) be the optimal consumption bundle given (p; !). Suppose the initial wealth is increased from ! to !0(> !), the budget set strictly expands. This implies that there exists some x0 2 B(p; !0) such that x0 x . Then, we obtain

v(p; !) := max

x2B(p;!0)u(x) u(x

0) > u(x ) = v(p; !) where the strict inequality comes from monotonicity of u. (b) Decreasing in p.

Answer:

For any two price vectors p0 p, and for any consumption bundle x 0, p0x px holds. This implies

x2B(p0; !) ) x 2 B(p; !)

and for any ! 0. Speci…cally, the optimal consumption bundle under p0 (and

!) is always feasible under p. Thus, the corresponding utility never decreases. (c) Quasi-convex in (p; !).

Answer:

Let B1, B2 and Bt be the budget sets available when prices and income are (p1; !1), (p2; !2) and (pt; !t), respectively, where

pt:= tp1+ (1 t)p2

!t:= t!1+ (1 t)!2. Then, we will show that

v(pt; !t) max[v(p1; !1); v(p2; !2)] for all t 2 [0; 1]. (1) This relation trivially holds when t = 0 or 1. So, in what follows we focus on t 2 (0; 1). Suppose (1) is not satis…ed. Then, there must exist some consumption

(2)

bundle x0 such that

x0 2Bt; x0 2= B1 and x0 2= B2. By de…nition of budget sets, we must have

p1x0 > !1 and p2x0 > !2. For any t 2 (0; 1), the following also holds:

tp1x0 > t!1 and (1 t)p2x0 > (1 t)!2. Adding, we obtain

(tp1+ (1 t)p2)x0 > t!1+ (1 t)!2 , ptx > yt,

which contradicts our assumption that x0 2 Bt. Therefore, (1) holds, i.e., v(p; !) is quasi-convex in (p; !).

2. Question 2 (15 points)

A good is called normal (resp. inferior) if consumption of it increases (resp. declines) as income increases, holding prices constant. Show the following claims. You can use the Slutsky equation (without proof) if it is needed.

(a) A decrease in the own price of a normal good will cause quantity demanded (Marshallian demand) to increase.

Answer:

The Slutsky equation says

@xi(p; !)

@pi

= @x

h i(p; u )

@pi

xi(p; !)@xi(p; !)

@! . (2)

Since the good i is assumed to be normal, @xi@!(p;!) > 0. So, the second term must be negative, which combined with the fact that @xhi@p(p;u )

i 0 implies that the right hand side must be negative. Thus, the own price e¤ect for a normal good is always negative.

(b) If an own price decrease causes a decline in quantity demanded (known as Gi¤en’s paradox), the good must be inferior.

Answer:

Suppose the right hand side of (2). Since the …rst term is always non-positive, the second term must be strictly positive. Thus @xi@!(p;!) < 0, i.e., the good should be inferior.

(c) In a two-good case, if one good is inferior, the other good must be normal.

(3)

Suppose both goods are inferior, and let x be the optimal cumsumption bun- dle under (p; !). If the initial wealth is increased from ! to !0(> !). Then, by de…nition of inferior goods, the optimal consumption bundle under (p; !0), denoted by x0, satis…es x0 x . This implies

px0 px = ! < !0, which contradicts Walras’ law.

3. Question 3 (20 points)

Consider the consumer problem where the utility function and the budget constraint are given by

u(x1; x2) = x

1 2

1x

1 3

2, and

! = p1x1+ p2x2,

respectively. Calculate (i) the Marshallian demand, (ii) the indirect utility function, (iii) the Hicksian demand, and (iv) the expenditure function.

Answer is given in class. 4. Queston 4 (15 points)

Consider the indirect utility function given by v(p1; p2; !) = !

p1+ p2

. (a) What are the (Marshallian) demand functions? (b) What is the expenditure function?

(c) Find a direct utility function which is consistent with the above indirect utility function.

Answer is given in class. 5. Question 5 (10 points)

Suppose the production function f satis…es (i) f (0) = 0, (ii) increasing, (iii) con- tinuous, (iv) quasi-concave, and (v) constant returns to scale. Then, show that f must be a concave function of x.

Answer:

Take any x1 0 and x2 0, and let y1 = f (x1) and y2 = f (x2). Then, y1; y2 > 0 because f (0) = 0 and f is strictly increasing. Therefore, because f is homogeneous of degree one,

f (x

1

y1) = f ( x2 y2) = 1.

(4)

Because f is quasi-concave, f (tx

1

y1 +

(1 t)x2

y2 ) 1 for all t 2 [0; 1]. (3)

Now choose t = y1y+y1 2 (and1 t = y1y+y2 2). Then (3) becomes

f ( x

1

y1+ y2 + x2

y1+ y2) 1. Again invoking the homogeneity of f gives us

f (x1+ x2) y1+ y2 = f (x1) + f (x2). (4) By continuity, (4) holds for all x1; x2 0 (not only x1; x2 0). Note that for any two vector x0; x00 0 and for any t 2 [0; 1], we have

f (tx0) = tf (x0) and f ((1 t)x00) = (1 t)f (x00).

Substituting x1 = tx0 and x2 = (1 t)x00 into (4), we conclude that f (tx0+ (1 t)x00) tf (x00) + (1 t)f (x00), as desired.

6. Question 6 (15 points)

A real-valued function f ( ) is called superaddittive if f (x1+ x2) f (x1) + f (x2).

Show that every cost function is superadditive in prices. Use this property to prove that the cost function is nondecreasing in input prices.

Answer:

We have to show that for any y > 0, the following inequality holds:

c(w1+ w2; y) c(w1; y) + c(w2; y) (5) Let x12; x1; x2 be the optimal conditional input demand to produce y for each price vector. Then, we obtain

c(w1+ w2; y) = (w1+ w2)x12 = w1x12+ w2x12. (6) By de…nition of c( ),

w1x12 c(w1; y) and w2x12 c(w2; y)

(5)

must hold. Substituting them into (6), we achieve (5). 7. Qusetion 7 (10 points)

Let c(w; y) be the cost function generated by the production function f and suppose the following two maximization problems (1) and (2) have solutions y and x 0,respectively.

(1) : max

y 0 py c(w; y)

(2) : max

x2RK+ 1

pf (x) wx

(a) Show that by = f (x ) solves (1). Answer:

Suppose not. Then, there must exist y0 6= by(= f (x )) and x0 such that

py0 c(w; y0) > pby c(w; by) (7) and

y0 = f (x0). Note that (7) can be written as

pf (x0) wx0 > pf (x ) w(x ),

which contradicts to the assumption that x is an optimal solution of (2). (b) Show that if c(w; y ) = wbxand y = f (bx), then bxsolves (2).

Answer:

Suppose not. Then, there must exist x006=bxsuch that pf (x00) wx00 > pf (bx) wbx. Let y00 = f (x00). Then, this inequality can be written as

py00 c(w; y00) > py c(w; y ),

which contradicts to the assumption that y is an optimal solution of (1).

参照

関連したドキュメント

By considering the p-laplacian operator, we show the existence of a solution to the exterior (resp interior) free boundary problem with non constant Bernoulli free boundary

Figure 7: The coding of the boundary of a polyomino, starting from A and moving in a clockwise sense; its salient (resp. reentrant) points are indicated by black (resp. A

In this section we state our main theorems concerning the existence of a unique local solution to (SDP) and the continuous dependence on the initial data... τ is the initial time of

We observe that the elevation of the water waves is in the form of traveling solitary waves; it increases in amplitude as the wave number increases k, as shown in Figures 3a–3d,

We remind that an operator T is called closed (resp. The class of the paraclosed operators is the minimal one that contains the closed operators and is stable under addition and

Then the strongly mixed variational-hemivariational inequality SMVHVI is strongly (resp., weakly) well posed in the generalized sense if and only if the corresponding inclusion

Tuyen proved that a regular space with a locally countable sn-network (resp., weak base) if and only if it is a compact-covering (resp., compact-covering quotient) compact and

In particular, if (S, p) is a normal singularity of surface whose boundary is a rational homology sphere and if F : (S, p) → (C, 0) is any analytic germ, then the Nielsen graph of