• 検索結果がありません。

Lecture note 7 最近の更新履歴 Keisuke Kawata's HP

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2018

シェア "Lecture note 7 最近の更新履歴 Keisuke Kawata's HP"

Copied!
25
0
0

読み込み中.... (全文を見る)

全文

(1)

Keisuke Kawata

ISS, UTokyo

(2)

DMP model

• DMP is a simple search model beyond the Diamond paradox.

• The model is popular to incorporate the unemployment. e.g.,)

Business Cycle: Survey Shimer (2010)

Urban/regional economics: Survey Zenou (2009)

International trade: (Classical trade theory) Davidson, Martin, & (New New Trade theory) Helpman, E., & Itskhoki, O. (2010)

Housing market: Wheaton (1990)

(3)

Alternative model: Competitive search model

• There are some alternative search models

⇒ A important alternative model is the competitive search model (Moen 1997).

• Competitive search model still uses the matching function, while has following two unique futures

Price posting: Firms first post and committee wage before meetings. Directed search: Workers can search focusing on a specific wage level.

• Similar properties but more tractable in some cases.

• just change the search model from DMP to competitive search

(4)

Plan

1. One shot model with homogeneous agents 2. One shot model with heterogeneous firms

(5)

1. Settings: Sub-markets

• We use su - a kets a alog ← game-theoretic foundation (Burdett, Shi, Wright 2001.

• A labor market is divided into sub-markets. Each sub-market is characterized by wage-level, in which all firms offer same wage.

⇒Firms and workers can choose searching sub-market.

• Matching process within sub-markets is still descried by the matching function.

(6)

1. Setting: Other assumption

• There are a unit mass workers and many firms.

• We start from a simple case where workers and firms are risk-nuetral and homogeneous.

⇒ Expected utility of a worker applying sub-market with w is

+ − ,

while the expected profit of a firm in the sub-market is

� − − �

• Workers can only one sub-market (without multiple applications).

(7)

1. Setting: Timing

• We summary the model setting as timing of game 1. Wage-posting (selecting sub-market).

2. Workers observe the number of vacancies in each sub-market and then select a sub-market.

3. Matching process.

• We consider two cases

Exogeneous firm entry: The number of vacancies is exogenously given.

Endogenous firm entry: The number is determined by the zero profits condition in the first stage.

(8)

1. Equilibrium: third stage

• Because the constant-return-to-scale matching function is assumed, the job- finding and filling probabilities in a sub-market w are

= ,

= ,

where

= ,

and are numbers of vacancies and seekers in the sub-market.

(9)

1. Definition: equilibrium

• The market equilibrium is defined over { , } and expected utility and profits, which is satisfied

1. A worker chooses sub-market to maximize her utility. 2. A firm chooses sub-market to maximize her profits. 3. Feasibility condition;

∫ � = , � ∫ � =

where v is the total number of firms.

4. Zero profit condition in the endogenous firm entry case.

(10)

1. Equilibrium: second stage

• I e uili iu , et ee a ti e su -markets ( , > ), the arbitrage condition must be hold;

+ − = + − .

⇒ Let defi e the a ket-le el utilit = max∈� + − .

Because each worker cannot be manipulate the market tightness, the arbitrage condition can be summarized as

+ − =

(11)

1. Equilibrium: first stage

• Ea h fi a ot a ipulate the a ket-le el utilit , the posted wage of a firm is given by

max � −

subject to

= + − .

Above problem is mathematically equivalent to max,� � − subject to

= + − .

(12)

1. Equilibrium: wage and tightness

• The first order conditions can be summarized are

= � + − ,

Where = − / .

←same as in the DMP with the Hosios condition. Substituting into the constrain obtains

= � − + .

⇒ The equilibrium wage and tightness as a function of the market level utility.

(13)

1. Exogeneous firm entry

• Let suppose the number of vacancies is given.

⇒Feasibility condition determines the market tightness as = .

⇒The equilibrium utility is endogenously determined.

= � − + .

⇒ If the number of vacancies are relatively larger than the number of seeker, the equilibrium utility is then high.

(14)

1. Endogenous firm entry

• Let suppose the number of vacancies is determined by the zero-profits condition:

= � − − �.

Incorporating = � + − � yields

= − � − − �

← determining same equilibrium as in the DMP with the Hosios condition.

(15)

1. Efficiency properties

• The social welfare still can be defined as

�� = , � + − , − �

Exogeneous firm entry: Trivially efficient. Endogenous firm entry: Efficient.

← Why?

(16)

1. Efficiency properties: Intuition

• The equilibrium condition with the endogenous entry can be summarized by Fi ’s opti izatio p o le

max,� � − , . . , = + − ,

and the zero profit condition = � − − �.

⇒an equivalent condition is

max,� + − , . . , = � − − �.

Wo ke ’s utilit is a i ized ith the ze o p ofit o ditio

(17)

1. Efficiency properties: Intuition

• The optimization problem can be more modified as

max � + − �

⇒ Social welfare is maximized in the equilibrium.

• The efficiency properties of the competitive search model is from same intuition as in the Warlasian market

Warlasian market: Competition to attract (employed) workers. Competitive search: Competition to attract applicants.

(18)

2. Heterogeneous firms: Setting

• Supposing firms with heterogeneous productivities.

• We modify the timing of game is as follow

0. D a i g fi ’s p odu ti it f o � � and firm entry after observing it. 1. Wage posting

2. Workers observe the number of vacancies in each sub-market and then select a sub-market.

3. Matching process.

← The equilibrium properties are similar even if firm productivity is determined

(19)

2. Definition: equilibrium

• Fi ’s e t de isio -making can be characterized by threshold strategy: a firm entries the market if and only if � ≥ ത�.

• The market equilibrium is defined over { � , � , ത�} and expected utility and profits, which is satisfied

1. A worker chooses sub-market to maximize her utility. 2. A firm chooses sub-market to maximize her profits. 3. Feasibility condition;

∫ � = , � ∫ � =

where v is the total number of firms. 4. Zero profit condition

(20)

2. Equilibrium wage and tightness

• We can obtain the similar equilibrium conditions after stage 1. Wage condition: � = � +

Market tightness given market utility: = � − + .

⇒With productivity, wage has positive relationship, while tightness has negative relationship.

Why?: More productive firms have stronger incentive to fill their vacancies because they have higher opportunity cost

→ paying higher wage and attracting more seeker lower tightness

(21)

2. Equilibrium threshold and utility

• The zero profit condition leads the equilibrium threshold ത� as

= ത� ത� − ത� − �

= ത� − ത� − − �.

⇒ Feasibility condition leads

ത�

−1� � �� =

← determining the equilibrium utility.

(22)

2. DMP VS competitive search

• Both DMP and competitive search can explain the wage variation as a result of productivity difference. But intuitions are different;

DMP: As a result of the bargaining, more productive firms pay higher wage.

Co petiti e sea h: As a fi ’s opti izatio sea h eha io , o e p odu ti it firms pay higher wage to attract more workers.

(23)

3. Conclusion

• Competitive search model suppose price-posting and directed search with the matching function.

← have similar property as DMP with the Hosios condition.

(24)

Related Literature

Job search

Business cycle: Shimer, R. (2010). Labor Markets and Business Cycles. Princeton University Press.

Urban/region: Zenou, Y. (2009). Urban labor economics. Cambridge University Press.

International Trade: (Classical) Davidson, C., Martin, L., & Matusz, S. (1999). Trade and search generated unemployment. Journal of International Economics, 48(2), 271-299.

(New New Trade theory) Helpman, E., & Itskhoki, O. (2010). Labour market rigidities, trade and unemployment. The Review of Economic Studies, 77(3), 1100-1137.

(25)

Related Literature

Housing search

Wheaton, W. C. (1990). Vacancy, search, and prices in a housing market matching model. Journal of Political Economy, 98(6), 1270-1292.

Intermediator

Antras, P., & Costinot, A. (2011). Intermediated trade. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126(3), 1319-1374.

Fernández-Blanco, J. (2012). A directed search model of intermediated trade. European Economic Review, 56(8), 1481-1494.

参照

関連したドキュメント

Zaslavski, Generic existence of solutions of minimization problems with an increas- ing cost function, to appear in Nonlinear

In [10, 12], it was established the generic existence of solutions of problem (1.2) for certain classes of increasing lower semicontinuous functions f.. Note that the

Under certain assumptions on the sequence (P N ) N≥0 (which still allow for the standard probabilis- tic models of algorithms associated with binary search trees, digital search

Making use, from the preceding paper, of the affirmative solution of the Spectral Conjecture, it is shown here that the general boundaries, of the minimal Gerschgorin sets for

For performance comparison of PSO-based hybrid search algorithm, that is, PSO and noising-method-based local search, using proposed encoding/decoding technique with those reported

We present sufficient conditions for the existence of solutions to Neu- mann and periodic boundary-value problems for some class of quasilinear ordinary differential equations.. We

The last sections present two simple applications showing how the EB property may be used in the contexts where it holds: in Section 7 we give an alternative proof of

Using the batch Markovian arrival process, the formulas for the average number of losses in a finite time interval and the stationary loss ratio are shown.. In addition,