• 検索結果がありません。

advmacro Takeki Sunakawa NKMP2

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2018

シェア "advmacro Takeki Sunakawa NKMP2"

Copied!
39
0
0

読み込み中.... (全文を見る)

全文

(1)

Monetary Policy Tradeoffs:

Discretion vs. Commitment

Takeki Sunakawa

Advanced Macroeconomics at Tohoku University

(2)

Introduction

The efficient allocation is obtained under fully flexible prices. The optimal policy fully stabilizes the price level.

In practice, central banks face short-run tradeoffs: inflation vs. real variables such as output and employment.

We need a monetary policy design in environment in which the central bank faces a nontrivial tradeoff.

(3)

The case of an efficient steady state

Consider a situation in which the flexible price equilibrium allocation is inefficient. The natural level of output ytn deviates from its efficient counterpart yet in the short run. On the other hand, yn= yeholds in the long run.

Some real imperfections generates a time-varying gap ut≡ ytn− yet even in the absence of price rigidities.

(4)

The CB’s problem

The central bank (CB hereafter) will minimize the welfare loss function:

E0

X t=0

βt π2t+ ϑx2t

,

where xt≡ yt− yteis the welfare-relevant output gap with ytedenoting the efficient level of output. ϑ = κ/ǫ is the weight of output gap fluctuations. Minimization is subject to

πt= βEtπt+1+ κxt+ ut, where ut≡ κ(yet− ytn).

[Note that ˜xt= yt− ynt = (yt− yte)

| {z }

xt

+ (yet− ytn)

| {z }

ut

.]

(5)

Cost-push shock

ut follows the exogenous AR(1) process

ut= ρuut−1+ εut,

where ρu∈ [0, 1) and εut is white noise with variance σ2u. ut generates a tradeoff between stabilizing πt and stabilizing xt.

(6)

Optimal Discretionary Policy

Each period the CB minimizes the period losses πt2+ ϑx2t, subject to the constraint

πt= κxt+ νt,

where νt≡ βEtπt+1+ utis taken as given by the central bank, as there are no endogenous state variables.

(7)

Optimal Discretionary Policy, cont’d

The optimality condition is given by xt= −κ

ϑπt, for t = 0, 1, 2, ....

Substituting it into the NKPC and after some manipulation (e.g., undetermined coefficient method), we have

πt = ϑ

κ2+ ϑ(1 − βρ)ut,

πt = − κ

κ2+ ϑ(1 − βρ)ut.

(8)

Optimal Commitment Policy

Now we assume that the CB is able to commit to future policies. The CB will choose a state-contingent sequence {xt, πt}t=0so as to minimize

E0

X t=0

βt π2t+ ϑx2t

,

subject to

πt= βEtπt+1+ κxt+ ut, and utfollows the AR(1) process:

ut= ρuut−1+ εut.

(9)

Optimal Commitment Policy, cont’d

It is useful to set up the Lagrangian as

L = E0

X t=0

βt 1 2 π

2 t + ϑx

2 t

+ ξtt− βEtπt+1− κxt)

 ,

where {ξt} is a sequence of Lagrange multipliers. The FONCs are

ϑxt− κξt= 0, πt+ ξt− ξt−1= 0,

for t = 0, 1, 2, ...,given ξ−1= 0, because there is no commitment in period 0.

(10)

Optimal Commitment Policy, cont’d

Combining the two, we have

x0= −κ ϑπ0, and

xt− xt−1= −κ ϑπt for t = 1, 2, 3, ....

(11)

Solving for the policy function under commitment

We assume: xt= axut+ bxxt−1and πt= aπut+ bπxt−1with the initial condition x−1= 0.

Substitute them into the NKPC and the tradeoff equation, aπut+ bπxt−1 = βEt(aπut+1+ bπxt) + κxt+ ut,

= (1 + βρuaπ)ut+ (βbπ+ κ)(axut+ bxxt−1),

= (1 + (βbπ+ κ)ax+ βρuaπ)ut+ (βbπ+ κ)bxxt−1.

aπut+ bπxt−1 = −(ϑ/κ) (xt− xt−1) ,

= −(ϑ/κ) (axut+ (bx− 1)xt−1) .

(12)

Solving for the policy function under commitment, cont’d

Then we have

aπ = −(ϑ/κ)ax

bπ = (ϑ/κ)(1 − bx)

aπ = 1 + (βbπ+ κ)ax+ βρuaπ, bπ = (βbπ+ κ)bx

These can be solved for

ax= −(κ/ϑ)/[β(δ+− ρu)], aπ= 1/[β(δ+− ρu)], bx= δ∈ (0, 1), bπ= (ϑ/κ)(1 − δ). where δ± =1 ±p1 − 4βγ2/ (2βγ) is the solution of a quadratic equation βγδ2− δ + γ = 0 where γ = (1 + β + κ2/ϑ)−1.

(13)

Discretion vs. Commitment: ρ

u

= 0.0 (when α = 0)

0 5 10

-2 -1.5 -1 -0.5

0 Output gap

0 5 10

-0.2 -0.1 0 0.1

0.2 Inflation

0.1 0.15

0.2 Price level

0.5 1

1.5 u

(14)

Discretion vs. Commitment: ρ

u

= 0.8 (when α = 0)

0 5 10

-2 -1.5 -1 -0.5

0 Output gap

0 5 10

-0.1 0 0.1 0.2

0.3 Inflation

0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8

1 Price level

0.5 1

1.5 u

(15)

The case of a distorted steady state

Consider the case in which there is a permanent gap x ≡ yn− ye. Specifically,

Un Uc

= (1 − Φ)M P N,

where Φ ≥ 0 measures the wedge between the marginal product of labor and marginal rate of substitution.

For example, monopolistic competition and associated markup is a source of the distortion, Φ ≡ 1 − [(1 − τ )M]−1≥ 0.

(16)

Second-order approximation to the household utility

Note that −Un/Uc= (1 − Φ)M P N = (1 − Φ)C/N implies (1 − Φ)UcC = −UnN . Then we have

Ut− U UcC

 ˆ

yt(1 + zt) +1 − σ 2 yˆ

2 t



−(1 − Φ)

 ˆ

yt(1 + zt) + dt+1 + ϕ

2 yt− at)

2



+ t.i.p.,

= Φ

 ˆ

yt(1 + zt) + dt+1 + ϕ

2 yt− at)

2





dt+σ + ϕ 2 yˆ

2

t + (σ + ϕ)ˆytat



+ t.i.p.,

= Φˆyt



dt+σ + ϕ 2 yˆ

2

t + (σ + ϕ)ˆytat



+ t.i.p.,

Under the small distortion assumption, the product of Φ with second-order terms is negligible. Also, Φˆytcan be considered as a second-order term.

(17)

The CB’s problem: The case of small SS distortions

Under the small distortion assumption, the welfare loss function is given by

E0

X t=0

βt 1 2 π

2 t + ϑˆx2t

− Λˆxt

 ,

where Λ ≡ Φλ/ǫ > 0 and ˆxt≡ xt− x with x ≡ yn− ye. Similarly, the NKPC can be written as

πt= βEtπt+1+ κˆxt+ ut.

(18)

Optimal Discretionary Policy

Each period the CB minimizes the period losses 1

2 π

2 t + ϑˆx

2 t

− Λˆxt,

subject to the constraint

πt= κˆxt+ νt,

where νt≡ βEtπt+1+ utis taken as given by the central bank.

(19)

Optimal Discretionary Policy, cont’d

The optimality condition is given by ˆ xt=Λ

ϑ κ ϑπt, for t = 0, 1, 2, ....

Substituting it into the NKPC and we have

πt = Λκ

κ2+ ϑ(1 − β) +

ϑ

κ2+ ϑ(1 − βρ)ut, ˆ

xt = Λ(1 − β) κ2+ ϑ(1 − β)

κ

κ2+ ϑ(1 − βρ)ut. The constant terms are known asthe inflation bias.

(20)

Optimal Commitment Policy

The Lagrangian is set up as

L = E0

X t=0

βt 1 2 π

2 t+ ϑˆx

2 t

− Λˆxt+ ξtt− βEtπt+1− κˆxt)

 ,

where {ξt} is a sequence of Lagrange multipliers. The FONCs are

ϑxt− κξt− Λ = 0, πt+ ξt− ξt−1= 0, for t = 0, 1, 2, ... and ξ−1= 0.

(21)

Optimal Commitment Policy, cont’d

Combining the two, we have

ˆ x0= −κ

ϑπ0+ Λ ϑ, and

ˆ

xt− ˆxt−1= −κ ϑπt for t = 1, 2, 3, ....

Note that the equilibrium conditions has the same form in the case of the efficient steady state except for t = 0.

ˆ

x−1 = Λ/ϑ is given as the initial condition.

(22)

Initial dynamics

0 5 10

0 0.5 1 1.5

2 Output gap

0 5 10

0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2

0.25 Inflation

1 2

3 Price level

-0.5 0 0.5

1 u

(23)

The case of large SS distortions

When the steady state distortions are large, the naive LQ approximation is no longer correct.

There are two (three?) alternative approaches to overcome the problem.

1 Use a second-order approximation of the structural equations to replace the linear terms in the welfare function to obtain the correct LQ approximation (Benigno and Woodford, 2005).

2 Solve the original nonlinear Ramsey problem for the equilibrium conditions. Then log-linearize the resulting equilibrium conditions (Khan, King and Wolman, 2003).

(24)

The zero lower bound on nominal interest rates

Money has no nominal payoffs but otherwise is identical to short-term nominal debt. This fact may impose the zero lower bound (ZLB) on the nominal return of such debt:

it≥ 0. Then the CB minimizes

E0

X t=0

βt π2t+ ϑx2t

,

subject to

πt = βEtπt+1+ κxt,

xt ≤ xt+1+ σ−1t+1+ rtn) .

The last equation is anoccasionally binding constraint. The equality holds when it= 0.

(25)

The natural rate and the ZLB

We assume the natural rate rnt follows an exogenous deterministic path: In the steady state, rtn= ρ. Itunexpectedlydrops to and remains at

rnt = −ǫ < 0 for t = 0, 1, ..., tZ. From period tZ+ 1 onward, it reverts to rnt = ρ again.

We assumethe perfect foresight(get rid of expectational operators

hereafter). Agents know the subsequent path of the natural rate in period 0.

Whenever rnt < 0, the efficient allocation, implied by it= rnt, is no longer attainable.

(26)

Optimal Discretionary Policy

Each period the CB minimizes the period losses πt2+ ϑx2t, subject to the constraint

πt = κxt+ ν0,t, xt ≤ ν1,t,

where ν0,t≡ βEtπt+1 and ν1,t≡ xt+1+ σ−1t+1+ rtn) are taken as given.

(27)

Optimal Discretionary Policy, cont’d

The Lagrangian is given by L = 1

2 π

2 t+ ϑx2t

+ ξ1,tt− κxt− ν1,t) + ξ2,t(xt− ν2,t) .

The FONCs are

xt+ ξ1,t= 0, ϑxt− κξ1,t+ ξ2,t= 0, and the slackness conditions

ξ2,t≥ 0, it≥ 0, ξ2,tit= 0. for t = 0, 1, 2, ....

(28)

The solution

From t = tZ+ 1 onward, it= ρ > 0, ξ2,t= 0, and xt= πt= 0 hold. For t = 0, 1, ..., tZ, it= 0, ξ2,t> 0, and ϑxt= −κπt− ξ2,thold. Then we can solve the two equations backward

πt = βπt+1+ κxt,

xt = xt+1+ σ−1t+1+ rtn) , from t = tZ, tZ− 1, ..., 0, given xtZ+1 = πtZ+1 = 0.

(29)

Optimal Commitment Policy

The CB will choose a state-contingent sequence {xt, πt}t=0so as to minimize

E0

X t=0

βt π2t+ ϑx2t,

subject to

πt = βπt+1+ κxt,

xt ≤ xt+1+ σ−1t+1+ rtn) .

(30)

Optimal Commitment Policy, cont’d

It is useful to set up the Lagrangian as

L = E0

X t=0

βt 1 2 π

2 t + ϑx

2 t

+ ξ1,tt− βπt+1− κxt)

2,t xt− xt+1− σ−1t+1+ rnt). The FONCs are

πt+ ξ1,t− ξ1,t−1− (βσ)−1ξ2,t−1 = 0, ϑxt− κξ1,t+ ξ2,t− β−1ξ2,t−1 = 0, and the slackness conditions

ξ2,t≥ 0, it≥ 0, ξ2,tit= 0.

for t = 0, 1, 2, ..., given the initial conditions ξ1,−1= ξ2,−1= 0.

(31)

A conjectured solution

The solution is conjectured and verified as follows;

1 From t = 0 to tC ≥ tZ , it= 0 and ξ2,t> 0.

2 For t = tC+ 1, it= 0, ξ2,t= 0 and ξ2,t> 0.

3 From t = tC+ 2 and onward, it> 0 and ξ2,t= ξ2,t−1 = 0,

(32)

t = t

C

+ 2 and onward

Note that ξ2,t= ξ2,t−1 = 0, then

πt+ ξ1,t− ξ1,t−1= 0, ϑxt− κξ1,t= 0, πt= βπt+1+ κxt, hold, given the initial condition ξ1,tC+1.

These equations can be solved for

xtC+2+k = −κδ

k+1

ϑ ξ1,tC+1, πtC+2+k = (1 − δ)δkξ1,tC+1. for k = 0, 1, 2, .... [check by yourself]

(33)

t = t

C

+ 1

Note that itC+1> 0 and ξ2,tC+1= 0, then

πtC+1+ ξ1,tC+1− ξ1,tC − (βσ)−1ξ2,tC = 0, ϑxtC+1− κξ1,tC+1− β−1ξ2,tC = 0,

πtC+1= β (1 − δ)ξ1,tC+1

| {z }

tC +2

+κxtC+1,

hold.

By substituting out ξ1,tC+1= [β(1 − δ)]−1tC+1− κxtC+1), we have [1 + β(1 − δ)]πtC+1− κxtC+1− β(1 − δ)ξ1,tC− [(1 − δ)/σ]ξ2,tC = 0, [β(1 − δ)ϑ + κ2]xtC+1− κπtC+1− (1 − δ)ξ2,tC = 0.

(34)

t = 0, 1, ..., t

C

and so on

Note that it= 0, then

πt = βπt+1+ κxt,

xt = xt+1+ σ−1t+1+ rtn) , hold, where

rnt =

(−ρ, when t = 0, 1, ..., tZ, ρ, when t = tZ+ 1, ..., tC. In addition, the original FONCs

πt+ ξ1,t− ξ1,t−1− (βσ)−1ξ2,t−1 = 0, ϑxt− κξ1,t+ ξ2,t− β−1ξ2,t−1= 0,

hold for t = 0, ..., tC+ 1, given the initial conditions ξ1,−1= ξ2,−1= 0.

(35)

The algorithm for the solution

The algorithm is as follows:

1 Fix tC≥ tZ. Solve 4 × (tC+ 2) equations for 4 × (tC+ 2) variables {xt, πt, ξ1,tξ2,t}tt=0C+1.

2 Obtain xt

C+2+k = −κδk+1ϑ ξ1,tC+1 and πtC+2+k= (1 − δ)δkξ1,tC+1 for k = 0, 1, ..., given ξ1,tC+1 at hand.

3 Check it= rn

t + πt+1+ σ(xt+1− xt) = 0 for t = 0, 1, ...tC and it> 0 t = tC+ 1, .... If not, increase tC and do 1-3 again.

(36)

The relevant equations

 xt

πt



=

 1 σ1 κ β +κσ



| {z }

A

 xt+1

πt+1

 +

 1 σκ σ

 rnt,

for t = 0, 1, ..., tC,

 xtC+1

πtC+1



=

 −κ 1 + β(1 − δ)

β(1 − δ) +κϑ2κϑ

−1

β(1 − δ) 1−δσ 0 1−δϑ



| {z }

M

×

 ξ1,tC

ξ2,tC

 ,

 ξ1,t

ξ2,t



=

 1 (βσ)−1 κ β−1(1 + κσ−1)



| {z }

H

 ξ1,t−1

ξ2,t−1



 0 1 ϑ κ



| {z }

J

 xt

πt

 ,

(37)

The relevant equations, cont’d

These equations can be stacked into















I2 −A

J I2

I2 −A

−H J I2

. .. . ..

−M I2

−H J I2



































 x0

π0

ξ1,0

ξ2,0

x1

π1

ξ1,1

ξ2,1

... xtC+1

πtC+1

ξ1,tC+1























=























rn0 κrσn0

σ

0 0

rn1 κrσn1

σ

0 0 ... 0 0 0























 .

(38)

Discretion vs. Commitment with the ZLB (when α = 0)

0 5 10

-15 -10 -5 0

5 Output gap

0 5 10

-60 -40 -20 0

20 Inflation

0 2 4

6 Nominal rate

0

5 Natural rate

(39)

Caveats

We have assumed the perfect foresight.

Uncertaintyabout the natural rate matters. We need to solve the model with stochastic settings (e.g., Adam and Billi, 2006; 2007, Nakov, 2008).

参照

関連したドキュメント

Additionally, we describe general solutions of certain second-order Gambier equations in terms of particular solutions of Riccati equations, linear systems, and t-dependent

In the second computation, we use a fine equidistant grid within the isotropic borehole region and an optimal grid coarsening in the x direction in the outer, anisotropic,

Keywords: continuous time random walk, Brownian motion, collision time, skew Young tableaux, tandem queue.. AMS 2000 Subject Classification: Primary:

Specifically, restricting attention to traveling wave solutions of the relaxation model (1.3), the first-order approximation (1.4), and the associated second-order approximation

The first case is the Whitham equation, where numerical evidence points to the conclusion that the main bifurcation branch features three distinct points of interest, namely a

Then it follows immediately from a suitable version of “Hensel’s Lemma” [cf., e.g., the argument of [4], Lemma 2.1] that S may be obtained, as the notation suggests, as the m A

This paper presents an investigation into the mechanics of this specific problem and develops an analytical approach that accounts for the effects of geometrical and material data on

The object of this paper is the uniqueness for a d -dimensional Fokker-Planck type equation with inhomogeneous (possibly degenerated) measurable not necessarily bounded