• 検索結果がありません。

Lec1 13 最近の更新履歴 yyasuda's website

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2017

シェア "Lec1 13 最近の更新履歴 yyasuda's website"

Copied!
13
0
0

読み込み中.... (全文を見る)

全文

(1)

Lecture 13: Production Economy

Advanced Microeconomics I

Yosuke YASUDA

Osaka University, Department of Economics yasuda@econ.osaka-u.ac.jp

November 18, 2014

1 / 13

(2)

From Pure Exchange to Production Economy

Previous lecture considered the general equilibrium in a pure exchange economy where all agents are consumers.

Now we expand our description of the economy to include production as well as consumption.

Rm We will find that most of the important properties of competitive market systems uncovered earlier continue to hold. In a general equilibrium model with production:

Consumers, 1, 2, ..., I, act to maximize utility subject to their budget constraints.

Firms, 1, 2, ..., J, seek to maximize profit. Both consumers and firms are price takers.

Firms’ profits are shared among individual consumers.

2 / 13

(3)

Firm Behavior (1)

Definition 1

Let Y denote the aggregate production possibilities set, defined as the sum of the individual production possibility sets:

Y =X

j∈J

Yj = {y | y =X

j∈J

yj where yj ∈ Yj}.

Let y(p) be the aggregate net supply function defined as the sum of the individual net supply functions:

y(p) =X

j∈J

yj(p).

where yj(p) associates to each vector p the profit-maximizing net output vector at those prices.

Rm Y represents all production plans that can be achieved by some distribution of production among J individual firms.

3 / 13

(4)

Firm Behavior (2)

The next theorem says that if each firm maximizes profits, then aggregate profits must be maximized. Conversely, if aggregate profits are maximized, then each firm’s profits must be maximized. Theorem 2

An aggregate production plan y maximizes aggregate profit, if and only if each firm’s production plan yj maximizes its individual profit for all j∈ J.

The theorem implies that there are two equivalent ways to construct the aggregate net supply function:

1 Add up the individual firms’ net supply functions.

2 Add up the individual firms’ production sets and then determine the net supply function that maximizes profits on this aggregate production set.

4 / 13

(5)

Firm Behavior (3)

Proof.

We only show “⇐”, since the converse is straightforward.

Let {yj}j∈J be a set of profit-maximizing production plans for the individual firms. Suppose that y =Pj∈Jyj is not (aggregate) profit-maximizing at prices p. This implies that there is some other production plan y=Pj∈Jyj with yj in Yj that has higher profits:

X

j∈J

pyj = pX

j∈J

yj > pX

j∈J

yj =X

j∈J

pyj.

Inspecting the sums on each side of this inequality, we see that some firm j must have higher profits at yj than at yj.

Rm In a capitalist economy or private ownership economy, consumers own firms and are entitled to a share of the profits.

5 / 13

(6)

Consumer Behavior (1)

Definition 3

Consumer i’s share of the profits of firm j is represented by 0 ≤ θij ≤ 1 for all i ∈ I and j ∈ J

where X

i∈I

θij = 1 for all j ∈ J.

That is, each firm is completely owned by individual consumers. Then, the budget constraint of each consumer i becomes:

pxi ≤ pei+X

j∈J

θijpyj(p).

Rm Given e i and θij, the budget set is characterized by p alone. Hence, consumer i’s demand function can be written as a function

of p, denoted by xi(p). 6 / 13

(7)

Consumer Behavior (2)

Definition 4

Let x(p) =Pi∈Ixi(p) be the aggregate (consumer) demand function, the sum of the individual demand functions.

The aggregate excess demand function is defined by z(p) = x(p) − y(p) − e

where e is the aggregate supply from consumers, e =Pi∈Iei. Walras’ law holds in the production economy for the same reason that it holds in the pure exchange economy.

Each consumer satisfies her budget constraint, so the economy as a whole has to satisfy an aggregate budget constraint. Theorem 5 (Walras’ law)

If ui is strictly increasing for all i∈ I, then pz(p) = 0 must hold for all p.

7 / 13

(8)

The Proof of Walras’ Law

Proof We expand z(p) according to its definition. pz(p) = p(x(p) − y(p) − e)

= p

 X

i∈I

xi(p) −X

j∈J

yj(p) −X

i∈I

ei

=X

i∈I

pxi(p) −X

j∈J

pyj(p) −X

i∈I

pei.

Since the budget constraint of every consumer holds with equality, pxi(p) = pei+X

j∈J

θijpyj(p).

Substituting it into the above equation, we obtain pz(p) =X

i∈I

pei+X

i∈I

X

j∈J

θijpyj(p) −X

j∈J

pyj(p) −X

i∈I

pei

=X

j∈J

pyj(p) −X

j∈J

pyj(p) = 0.

8 / 13

(9)

Competitive Equilibrium

The production economy is represented by (ui, ei, θij, Yj)i∈I,j∈J. Definition 6

An allocation-price pair (x, y, p) where p ≫ 0 is called a competitive (Walrasian) equilibrium, if z(p) = 0. The next theorem guarantees the existence of equilibrium. Theorem 7

Consider a production economy(ui, ei, θij, Yj)i∈I,j∈J. Suppose that the following conditions are satisfied:

Utility function ui is continuous, strongly increasing, and strictly quasiconcave for all i∈ I.

0∈ Yj ⊆ Rn, Yj is closed, bounded and strongly convex. y+Pi∈Iei ≫ 0 for some aggregate production vector y ∈ Y . Then, there exists at least one price vector p ≫ 0 such that z(p) = 0. That is, the competitive equilibrium price exists.

9 / 13

(10)

Competitive Equilibrium: Example (1)

Ex Consider a Robinson Crusoe economy where a consumer has the following Cobb-Douglas utility function for consumption x and leisure R and initial endowments e:

u(x, R) = xaR1−a

The consumer is endowed with one unit of labor/leisure and there is one firm that has a production function x = L1/2. Let the price of x be normalized by 1. Then, solve a competitive equilibrium price of labor, denoted by w.

Answer Let us first solve the profit maximization problem: maxL L

1/2

− wL

From the first order condition, 12L−1/2− w = 0, we obtain L(w) = 1

(2w)2, xs(w) = 1

2w, π(w) = 1 4w.

10 / 13

(11)

Competitive Equilibrium: Example (2)

Since the firm’s profits are distributed to the consumer, she solves: maxx,R x

aR1−a s.t. x+ wR = w + 1

4w

By the property of the Cobb-Douglas utility function, we obtain xd(w) = a

 w+ 1

4w



, R(w) = 1 − a w

 w+ 1

4w

 .

In a competitive equilibrium, the supply and demand for x coincide, xs(w) = xd(w) ⇔ 1

2w = a



w+ 1 4w



⇒ w = 2 − a 4a

1/2

.

Note that, by Walras’ law, the labor market also clears.

11 / 13

(12)

First Welfare Theorem

Theorem 8

If each ui is strictly increasing on Rn+, then every competitive equilibrium is Pareto efficient.

Proof Suppose not, and let (x, y) be a Pareto dominating allocation. Then, since consumers are maximizing utility,

pxi > pei+X

j∈J

θijpyj

must hold for all i ∈ I. Summing over consumers,

pX

i∈I

xi>X

i∈I

pei+X

j∈J

pyj. Feasibility of x, i.e., x = e + y, implies

p

 X

i∈I

ei+X

j∈J

yj

>X

i∈I

pei+X

i∈J

pyjX

j∈J

pyj >X

j∈J

pyj, which contradicts profit maximization by firms. 12 / 13

(13)

Second Welfare Theorem

Theorem 9

Suppose the conditions stated in the existence theorem are satisfied. Let(x, y) be a feasible Pareto efficient allocation. Then, there are income transfers, T1, ..., TI, satisfyingPi∈ITi = 0, and a price vector p such that for all j∈ J and for all i ∈ I.

1 y

j maximizes pyj s.t. yj ∈ Yj.

2 x

i maximizes ui(xi) s.t. pxi ≤ pei+Pj∈Jθijpyj + Ti.

Rm The transfer T i must be set equal to Ti= pxi

pei+X

j∈J

θijpyj

 Note that by feasibility of (x, y),

X

i∈I

Ti = pX

i∈I

(xi − ei) − pX

j∈J

yj = p(x− (e + y)) = 0.

13 / 13

参照

関連したドキュメント

To be specific, we evaluate the expected profits and variance of profits risk of the fashion supply chains, fashion retailers, and manufacturers under 1 the currently implemented

Most papers on economic growth considering the Solow-Swan or neoclassical model used the Cobb-Douglas specification of the production function, which describes a process with a

We give another global upper bound for Jensen’s discrete inequal- ity which is better than already existing ones.. For instance, we determine a new converses for generalized A–G and

As shown in the proof of Theorem 2.1, the Voronoi cells of ω n are asymptotically equal area, but do not approach regular hexagons. A comparison of the mesh ratios for several values

Yin, “Global existence and blow-up phenomena for an integrable two-component Camassa-Holm shallow water system,” Journal of Differential Equations, vol.. Yin, “Global weak

p≤x a 2 p log p/p k−1 which is proved in Section 4 using Shimura’s split of the Rankin–Selberg L -function into the ordinary Riemann zeta-function and the sym- metric square

In this contribution, we present algorithms which can be used to determine and visualize a production frontier in the form of an efficient hull in a 3D diagram in the case where

documents maintained pursuant to Article 43, that demonstrate the compliance with Chapter 4 and to check, for that purpose, the facilities used in the production of the good, through